Abstract
This paper reviews economic growth theory in the framework of economic development and explores the possibility of sustained growth in the People's Republic of China (PRC) in the long run. We argue that the PRC has the potential to sustain relatively high growth rates. First, since the technological gap with major developed countries still exists, the PRC can continue to enjoy its “advantage of backwardness” in the near future. Second, large-scale infrastructure investment, which began several decades ago, may possibly extend to the future and provide the country a basis for further growth. Third, structural readjustment, which is needed in many areas, should similarly be able to support the Chinese economy. This paper argues that to sustain long-term growth in the PRC, a number of general preconditions need to be fulfilled—these include well-functioning markets, a minimum amount of investment, continued structural upgrading, and effective government.
I. Introduction
Economic development of the People's Republic of China (PRC) over the past 30 years has been an intriguing phenomenon. The country provides an interesting case for the study of economic growth, especially the sources of growth and expectations about future performance. With the PRC's declining growth rate during the past 4 years, there have been heated debates recently on the potential growth rate of the country in the medium and long run. Lin (2012a) argues that the Chinese economy has the potential to grow by 8% annually for another 20 years beginning in 2008.
This paper attempts to provide answers to the question of whether or not the PRC can indeed maintain a relatively high growth rate in the coming decades. We first present a review of the history of growth performance over the past 35 years including the recent slowdown, which had triggered concern about long-run growth potential. We also provide a review of the various theories on sustaining growth in the long run, which serve as the basis for subsequent analysis of the PRC's growth potential. Finally, we discuss the preconditions for sustained growth.
II. Historical Review of the PRC's Growth Performance
The PRC has been experiencing extraordinary growth in the past 3 and a half decades, with annual gross domestic product (GDP) growth averaging 9.8% over the 35-year period since 1978. No country has ever grown as fast or for as long a time as the PRC during the past 35 years. Before the transition from a planned economy to a market economy in the late 1970s, the country had been trapped in poverty for centuries. However, it is now an upper-middle-income economy, with GDP per capita of over $6,000.
Prior to the late 1970s, the PRC failed to achieve dynamic growth, as it applied a strategy that prioritized the development of heavy industries. From the 1950s to the 1970s, the Chinese government subsidized the firms in priority sectors through various price distortions and protections. Such a strategy was clearly inconsistent with the comparative advantage of the country during the period. As a result, resources became misallocated, total factor productivity (TFP) remained low, and growth was driven mainly by input increases. Firms in the priority sectors became unviable in an open and competitive market. Despite annual GDP growth of 6.1% and the establishment of a complex system of advanced industries during 1952–1978, household consumption grew by only 2.3% annually during the period (Lin 2012a).
The PRC has achieved rapid growth since the start of economic reform in the late 1970s, with the extraordinary performance partly due to the adoption of a gradual, dual-track transition strategy. On one hand, the government provided protection in the form of transitory subsidies to prioritized heavy industry sectors to maintain stability. On the other hand, it liberalized entry into sectors where the country had comparative advantage based on factor endowments.
The PRC recently experienced a decline in economic growth, which had fallen from 10.4% in 2010 to 7.7% in 2013. This is the longest period of growth deceleration since the country's transition to a market economy in 1979 and has naturally raised concern about the sustainability of growth.
However, the slowdown had not been due to overinvestment, financial repression, the state-led growth model, or other internal structural problems frequently mentioned by observers predicting a crash in the Chinese economy.1 The recent slowdown of the Chinese economy in fact was mainly caused by external and cyclical factors—specifically, the slow recovery of advanced economies after the 2008 global financial crisis, which has repressed export growth, and the slowdown of the country's investment growth due to the completion of projects supported by the fiscal stimulus in the aftermath of the 2008 crisis (Figure 1).
These same factors triggered growth deceleration in other emerging market economies and in high-income economies. As seen in Figure 2, the slowdown in the PRC had been relatively mild compared to that in other countries.
Facing the potential of a “new normal” in high-income countries (i.e., protracted low growth), export growth will likely be subdued in the coming years. The PRC's growth will therefore have to depend on domestic demand—investment as well as consumption. How high the country's growth will be in the coming years meanwhile will depend on its potential growth rate.
III. Theories on Sustaining Growth in the Long Run
The development of theories of economic growth in the long run has been remarkable in the past half century. In this section, we review the basic features of some of the major theories in a framework of economic development.
The neoclassical growth model, developed in the mid-20th century, is an exogenous growth model of long-run growth set within the framework of neoclassical economics. In these models, the long-run growth rate is exogenously determined by either the savings rate (the Harrod–Domar model) or the rate of technical progress (the Solow model). Solow's model assumes that factors of production are paid according to the value of their marginal products. The marginal product of capital will fall if capital rises faster than labor, which is normal for a growing economy, leading to a fall in the growth rate of output.
Neoclassical growth theory therefore indicates a convergence or catch-up process in which developing countries acquire techniques and learn how to use them efficiently. This supports arguments for the PRC's long-run growth slowdown.
In the late 1980s, a number of economists began to analyze the nature and role of the residual element in neoclassical growth theories by making it endogenous (Romer 1986 and 1990, Lucas 1988). In endogenous growth theory, knowledge (technology) is the instrument of production that is not subject to diminishing returns. The theory tries to explain the lack of convergence by introducing the role of human capital, maintaining that economic growth is primarily the result of endogenous forces—e.g., investment in human capital, innovation, and knowledge—and not external forces.
Economic growth and convergence will be faster the more the economy is invested in human capital. Aghion and Howitt (1992) developed a model of growth through creative destruction in which innovations serve as the underlying source of growth. In their model, the amount of research in any period depends on the expected amount of research next period, which comes from created destruction. The growth rate and the variance of the growth rate are increasing functions of the size of innovation and skilled labor force, and the productivity of research.
Development economics uses growth theory to analyze economic growth in developing countries. The theories have come in three waves since the 1950s. The first wave involved structuralism (Rosenstein-Rodan 1943, Prebisch 1950, Singer 1950). Based on this thinking, governments were advised to develop industries that were too far advanced compared to their corresponding countries’ level of development and that went against comparative advantage. Firms were thus nonviable in competitive markets and needed government policy support for initial investment and continuous operation (Lin 2009).
The second wave of development thinking, neoliberalism, was encapsulated in the Washington Consensus. The term originally referred to the reform package put together by financial institutions based in Washington, DC and recommended to developing countries mired in crisis in the late 1990s. It has since been used to refer to a more general orientation toward a strongly market-based approach.
The Washington Consensus set up a standard for developing countries based on the successful practices of developed economies. It opposed governments playing a proactive role in facilitating entry of firms into sectors even if consistent with a country's comparative advantage. It also failed to recognize that distortions in developing countries may be endogenous and advised governments to immediately eliminate them, causing the collapse of previously prioritized sectors.
The third wave involved what is known as the new structural economics. This development theory argues that each country needs to adjust its economic structure in the process of development according to its comparative advantage as determined by factor endowments (Lin 2012b). It applies a neoclassical economics approach to understand the determinants of economic structure and its evolution. Industrial structure is assumed to be endogenous to the endowment structure, which is given at any specific time and changes over time.
New structural economics argues that, following comparative advantage, which is determined by the endowment structure, developing industries is the best way to upgrade the endowment structure and sustain industrial upgrading, income growth, and poverty reduction. If economic structure upgrading lags behind changes in endowments, the economy will be less competitive, and growth will be lower than the potential growth rate. Improvement of the economic structure provides new sources of growth by reducing the inefficiency within and between sectors. Structural upgrading needs a competitive market system and a facilitating state.
New structural economics also postulates that industrial policy is desirable, and that target industries should be in line with an economy's latent comparative advantage. The theory points out that as long as its government chooses the right set of policies, a developing country has the potential to grow continuously at 8% or more for several decades and to become a middle-income (or even high-income) country in one or two generations.
A review of growth theory in the framework of development tells us that sustaining growth depends on many factors, not just the productivity of physical capital. It is influenced as well by human capital, technology, and structural change in the economy. All these factors help to determine growth at the dynamic path.
IV. The PRC's Potential for Sustained Growth in the Long Run
By adopting correct policies, the PRC has the potential to sustain dynamic growth in the coming decades. This section presents possible reasons for the country's sustained long-run performance. These are the “advantage of backwardness,” the effect of capital investment, and structural readjustment.
A. The Advantage of Backwardness
A backward country has an advantage in economic development because it can borrow from a large backlog of technological innovations from advanced countries and adopt the latest technology without facing resistance from users of old technologies (Gerschenkron 1962). It can thus reduce the costs and risks of technological innovation, allowing it to grow faster than advanced countries. Since the late 1970s, the PRC has achieved high growth by tapping into this advantage of backwardness.
After 35 years of dynamic growth, does the PRC still have the potential to grow dynamically? The answer depends partly on whether or not the advantage of backwardness still exists. One way to measure this is by the gap between per capita GDP of the PRC and of the United States (US). Per capita GDP represents a country's average labor productivity, which in turn reflects the country's average technological level.
The PRC's per capita GDP measured in purchasing power parity (PPP) in 2008 as a percentage of that of the US was similar to that of Japan in 1951, the Republic of Korea in 1977, and Taipei,China in 1975 (Table 1). Annual GDP growth reached 9.2% in Japan during 1951–1971, 7.6% in the Republic of Korea during 1977–1997, and 8.3% in Taipei,China during 1975–1995. After 20 years of growth, Japan's per capita income measured in PPP was 66% that of the US in 1971. The corresponding percentage for the Republic of Korea was 50% in 1997, while that for Taipei,China was 54% in 1995.
. | 1951 . | 1967 . | 1971 . | 1975 . | 1977 . | 1987 . | 1995 . | 1997 . | 2008 . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Japan | 21 | 50 | 66 | 70 | 69 | 75 | 81 | 80 | 73 |
Republic of Korea | 8 | 11 | 15 | 19 | 21 | 32 | 48 | 50 | 63 |
Taipei,China | 9 | 14 | 18 | 22 | 24 | 39 | 54 | 57 | 67 |
PRC | 5 | 5 | 5 | 5 | 5 | 8 | 12 | 12 | 22 |
. | 1951 . | 1967 . | 1971 . | 1975 . | 1977 . | 1987 . | 1995 . | 1997 . | 2008 . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Japan | 21 | 50 | 66 | 70 | 69 | 75 | 81 | 80 | 73 |
Republic of Korea | 8 | 11 | 15 | 19 | 21 | 32 | 48 | 50 | 63 |
Taipei,China | 9 | 14 | 18 | 22 | 24 | 39 | 54 | 57 | 67 |
PRC | 5 | 5 | 5 | 5 | 5 | 8 | 12 | 12 | 22 |
GDP = gross domestic product, PRC = People's Republic of China, US = United States.
Note: GDP per capita is measured in 1990 international Geary-Khamis dollars.
Sources: Authors’ calculations; Maddison, Angus. 2011. Historical Statistics of the World Economy: 1–2008 A.D. Tables 2c and 5c. Available online at: www.ggdc.net/maddison/Historical_Statistics/horizontal-file_02-2010.xls.
Figure 3 shows the per capita GDP of Asian economies relative to the US per capita GDP from the year these economies started to take off—1951, 1975, 1977, and 1980, respectively, for Japan; Taipei,China; the Republic of Korea; and the PRC. Table 2 meanwhile indicates the degree of the advantage of backwardness in terms of stocks of capital and human capital per person (that is, by disentangling the extent that output per worker might be driven by differences in these stocks or other features).
. | GDP Per . | Capital . | Human . | No. of Persons . | TFP at Constant . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Capita . | Stock Per . | Capital Per . | Engaged . | National Prices . |
. | (2005 $) . | Capita (2005 $) . | Persona . | (millions) . | (2005 = 1) . |
US | 42,446 | 131,347 | 3.619 | 141.8 | 1.020 |
PRC | 9,324 | 33,134 | 2.579 | 784.4 | 1.193 |
PRC/US | 22.0% | 25.2% |
. | GDP Per . | Capital . | Human . | No. of Persons . | TFP at Constant . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Capita . | Stock Per . | Capital Per . | Engaged . | National Prices . |
. | (2005 $) . | Capita (2005 $) . | Persona . | (millions) . | (2005 = 1) . |
US | 42,446 | 131,347 | 3.619 | 141.8 | 1.020 |
PRC | 9,324 | 33,134 | 2.579 | 784.4 | 1.193 |
PRC/US | 22.0% | 25.2% |
PRC = People's Republic of China, TFP = total factor productivity, US = United States.
aIndex based on the number of years of schooling and returns to education.
Sources: Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania. Penn World Table 8.0. 2014. Available online at: http://www.rug.nl/research/ggdc/data/penn-world-table (accessed January 2015). National Bureau of Statistics. 2012. China Statistical Yearbook 2012. Beijing: China Statistics Press.
We use the average of the capital coefficient in the past 5 years estimated by the PWT for the period 2015–2028 and calculate the growth of GDP and its components from 2012 to 2028 assuming zero growth rate in the number of workers during the forecasting period (see Table 3).
. | . | Capital . | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Real GDP . | Stock . | ||||||||
. | (constant . | (constant . | Human . | Number . | TFP at . | |||||
. | 2005 . | 2005 . | Capital . | of Persons . | Constant . | |||||
. | national . | national . | Per . | Engaged . | National . | |||||
. | prices, %) . | prices, %) . | Persona (%) . | (%) . | Prices (%) . | |||||
Average | 7.8 | 8.1 | 1.2 | 2.3 | 2.0 | |||||
1952–2011 | ||||||||||
Average | 10.4 | 11.8 | 0.9 | 0.8 | 3.0 | |||||
2001–2011 | ||||||||||
Forecasts | Low | High | Low | High | Low | High | Low | High | Low | High |
2012 | 8.1 | 9.1 | 1.1 | 0.3 | 2.0 | |||||
2013 | 7.6 | 8.8 | 1.1 | 0.0 | 2.0 | |||||
2014 | 7.3 | 8.3 | 1.1 | 0.0 | 2.0 | |||||
2015–2020 | 6.1 | 8.0 | 6.8 | 8.8 | 1.0 | 1.2 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 1.7 | 2.3 |
2021–2028 | 5.4 | 7.6 | 5.5 | 7.5 | 1.0 | 1.2 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 1.7 | 2.3 |
. | . | Capital . | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Real GDP . | Stock . | ||||||||
. | (constant . | (constant . | Human . | Number . | TFP at . | |||||
. | 2005 . | 2005 . | Capital . | of Persons . | Constant . | |||||
. | national . | national . | Per . | Engaged . | National . | |||||
. | prices, %) . | prices, %) . | Persona (%) . | (%) . | Prices (%) . | |||||
Average | 7.8 | 8.1 | 1.2 | 2.3 | 2.0 | |||||
1952–2011 | ||||||||||
Average | 10.4 | 11.8 | 0.9 | 0.8 | 3.0 | |||||
2001–2011 | ||||||||||
Forecasts | Low | High | Low | High | Low | High | Low | High | Low | High |
2012 | 8.1 | 9.1 | 1.1 | 0.3 | 2.0 | |||||
2013 | 7.6 | 8.8 | 1.1 | 0.0 | 2.0 | |||||
2014 | 7.3 | 8.3 | 1.1 | 0.0 | 2.0 | |||||
2015–2020 | 6.1 | 8.0 | 6.8 | 8.8 | 1.0 | 1.2 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 1.7 | 2.3 |
2021–2028 | 5.4 | 7.6 | 5.5 | 7.5 | 1.0 | 1.2 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 1.7 | 2.3 |
GDP = gross domestic product, PRC = People's Republic of China, TFP = total factor productivity.
aIndex based on the number of years of schooling and returns to education.
Note: We use a capital coefficient of 0.59 for 2015–2028.
Source: Authors’ computations.
We assume the following in our economic analysis: a zero growth rate for the number of workers during 2015–2028, which is consistent with the population trend and age structure of the PRC, and a 1%–1.2% increase in human capital per person during 2015–2028, or slightly lower than the actual annual growth of human capital of 1.2% during 1952–2011.
We also assume that the country's capital stock will keep growing albeit at a moderate rate based on the assumptions of continued structural upgrading and discovery of new investment areas. The increase will be 6.8%–8.8% during 2015–2020 and 5.5%–7.5% during 2021–2028, lower than the actual growth rate of capital stock during 2001–2011 (11.8%) and 2013 (8.8%).
TFP growth will similarly decline slightly during the forecast period, as the PRC approaches the world technological frontier. We assume a growth rate of 1.7%–2.3% during 2015–2028, lower than the actual growth rate of 3% during 2001–2011.
Our growth accounting analysis shows that the GDP growth rate of the PRC will be in the range of 6.1%–8.0% before 2020 and 5.4%–7.6% during 2021–2018 if capital stock increases by 6.8% to 8.8% during 2015–2020 and by 5.5% to 7.5% during 2021–2028, human capital per person increases by 1% to 1.2% during 2015–2028, and TFP increases by 1.7% to 2.3% during 2015–2028. The assumptions are reasonable and conservative compared to growth rates in previous periods, which are also shown in Table 3.
To support our forecasts, we calculate using PWT data the average annual growth rates of physical capital, human capital, and TFP in Japan; the Republic of Korea; and Taipei,China during the same development stage that the PRC finds itself in currently. The results are shown in Table 4. Since the PRC is in a similar development stage as the Republic of Korea during 1977–1997 and Taipei,China during 1975–1995, it is likely that the country's capital stock and TFP will grow at similar rates in the near future.
. | Real GDP . | Capital Stock . | Human . | Number . | TFP at . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (constant 2005 . | (constant 2005 . | Capital . | of Persons . | Constant . |
. | national . | national . | Per . | Engaged . | National . |
. | prices, %) . | prices, %) . | Persona (%) . | (%) . | Prices (%) . |
Japan | 3.6 | 3.8 | 0.8 | 1.3 | 0.9 |
1951–1971 | |||||
Republic of Korea | 8.3 | 11.8 | 1.1 | 2.6 | 1.3 |
1977–1997 | |||||
Taipei,China | 8.3 | 10.7 | 1.1 | 2.5 | 1.4 |
1975–1995 |
. | Real GDP . | Capital Stock . | Human . | Number . | TFP at . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (constant 2005 . | (constant 2005 . | Capital . | of Persons . | Constant . |
. | national . | national . | Per . | Engaged . | National . |
. | prices, %) . | prices, %) . | Persona (%) . | (%) . | Prices (%) . |
Japan | 3.6 | 3.8 | 0.8 | 1.3 | 0.9 |
1951–1971 | |||||
Republic of Korea | 8.3 | 11.8 | 1.1 | 2.6 | 1.3 |
1977–1997 | |||||
Taipei,China | 8.3 | 10.7 | 1.1 | 2.5 | 1.4 |
1975–1995 |
GDP = gross domestic product, TFP = total factor productivity.
aIndex based on the number of years of schooling and returns to education.
Sources: Authors’ computations; Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania. Penn World Table 8.0. 2014. Available online at: http://www.rug.nl/research/ggdc/data/penn-world-table (accessed January 2015).
To prevent mistakes in forecasting, our assumptions about the growth rates of the PRC's capital stock are tailored to be more conservative than the actual growth rates of capital stock in the Republic of Korea during 1977–1997 (11.8%) and Taipei,China during 1975–1995 (10.7%).
If the PRC maintains an 8% growth in the next 2 decades, by 2030, the PRC's per capita income measured in PPP may reach about 50% of that of the US. The exploitation of the advantage of backwardness has and will allow the PRC to achieve extraordinary economic growth by reducing the costs of innovation, industrial upgrading, and social and economic transformation.
B. Large-Scale Infrastructure Investment
Public investments, say in infrastructure, may have a positive influence on long-run growth if it raises the marginal productivity of private capital. Barro (1990) develops a closed-economy endogenous growth model where government service is viewed as an input in private producers’ production function. The effects of public investment on private producers have also been analyzed in many empirical studies. Aschauer (1989), for instance, studied the US economy during 1949–1985 and found that public investment in infrastructure had maximum explanatory power for the productivity of private capital.
Continued large-scale infrastructure investment, which began when the Chinese economy started to reform and open up, could be another possible factor behind sustained growth in the near future. The PRC has made large-scale infrastructure investments over the past several decades, which updated the country's infrastructure in all sectors and raised productivity, with continued positive effects on future growth. Table 5 shows the gross capital formation in the PRC from 1991 to 2013.
. | Gross Capital Formation . | % of GDP . |
---|---|---|
. | (CNY billion) . | (expenditure approach) . |
1991 | 786.80 | 34.8 |
1992 | 1,008.63 | 36.6 |
1993 | 1,571.77 | 42.6 |
1994 | 2,034.11 | 40.5 |
1995 | 2,547.01 | 40.3 |
1996 | 2,878.49 | 38.8 |
1997 | 2,996.80 | 36.7 |
1998 | 3,131.42 | 36.2 |
1999 | 3,295.15 | 36.2 |
2000 | 3,484.28 | 35.3 |
2001 | 3,976.94 | 36.5 |
2002 | 4,556.50 | 37.8 |
2003 | 5,596.30 | 41.0 |
2004 | 6,916.84 | 43.0 |
2005 | 7,785.68 | 41.5 |
2006 | 9,295.41 | 41.7 |
2007 | 11,094.32 | 41.6 |
2008 | 13,832.53 | 43.8 |
2009 | 16,446.32 | 47.2 |
2010 | 19,360.39 | 48.1 |
2011 | 22,834.43 | 48.3 |
2012 | 25,277.32 | 47.8 |
2013 | 28,035.61 | 47.8 |
. | Gross Capital Formation . | % of GDP . |
---|---|---|
. | (CNY billion) . | (expenditure approach) . |
1991 | 786.80 | 34.8 |
1992 | 1,008.63 | 36.6 |
1993 | 1,571.77 | 42.6 |
1994 | 2,034.11 | 40.5 |
1995 | 2,547.01 | 40.3 |
1996 | 2,878.49 | 38.8 |
1997 | 2,996.80 | 36.7 |
1998 | 3,131.42 | 36.2 |
1999 | 3,295.15 | 36.2 |
2000 | 3,484.28 | 35.3 |
2001 | 3,976.94 | 36.5 |
2002 | 4,556.50 | 37.8 |
2003 | 5,596.30 | 41.0 |
2004 | 6,916.84 | 43.0 |
2005 | 7,785.68 | 41.5 |
2006 | 9,295.41 | 41.7 |
2007 | 11,094.32 | 41.6 |
2008 | 13,832.53 | 43.8 |
2009 | 16,446.32 | 47.2 |
2010 | 19,360.39 | 48.1 |
2011 | 22,834.43 | 48.3 |
2012 | 25,277.32 | 47.8 |
2013 | 28,035.61 | 47.8 |
GDP = gross domestic product, PRC = People's Republic of China.
A rough comparison with the US shows that the PRC's gross investment during 2010–2013 measured in US dollars and using official annual average exchange rates was greater than the US gross domestic investment during the period. Although the share of physical investment in GDP declined slightly in recent years, it will remain relatively high in the near future. The quality of physical investment also remains quite high in terms of operating profit, although it declined slightly in recent years.
Real estate investment has been an important part of investment in the PRC in the past 20 years. Table 6 shows the operating statistics of real estate firms in the country. The share of taxes and profits increased dramatically beginning in 2005 and continued to be relatively high until 2012. This suggests that investments in real estate and physical capital will keep growing at a comparatively high rate in the near future.
. | Revenue from Principal Business . | Share of Taxes and Profits . |
---|---|---|
. | (CNY100 million) . | (%) . |
1992 | 528.56 | 19.9 |
1993 | 1,135.91 | 22.2 |
1994 | 1,288.19 | 20.4 |
1995 | 1,731.66 | 13.5 |
1996 | 1,968.79 | 5.6 |
1997 | 2,218.46 | 4.2 |
1998 | 2,951.21 | 4.3 |
1999 | 3,026.01 | 3.6 |
2000 | 4,515.71 | 6.4 |
2001 | 5,471.66 | 7.3 |
2002 | 7,077.85 | 8.8 |
2003 | 9,137.27 | 10.1 |
2004 | 13,314.46 | 9.5 |
2005 | 14,769.35 | 13.2 |
2006 | 18,046.76 | 15.5 |
2007 | 23,397.13 | 17.5 |
2008 | 26,696.84 | 19.7 |
2009 | 34,606.23 | 21.1 |
2010 | 42,996.48 | 22.3 |
2011 | 44,491.28 | 21.6 |
2012 | 51,028.41 | 20.8 |
. | Revenue from Principal Business . | Share of Taxes and Profits . |
---|---|---|
. | (CNY100 million) . | (%) . |
1992 | 528.56 | 19.9 |
1993 | 1,135.91 | 22.2 |
1994 | 1,288.19 | 20.4 |
1995 | 1,731.66 | 13.5 |
1996 | 1,968.79 | 5.6 |
1997 | 2,218.46 | 4.2 |
1998 | 2,951.21 | 4.3 |
1999 | 3,026.01 | 3.6 |
2000 | 4,515.71 | 6.4 |
2001 | 5,471.66 | 7.3 |
2002 | 7,077.85 | 8.8 |
2003 | 9,137.27 | 10.1 |
2004 | 13,314.46 | 9.5 |
2005 | 14,769.35 | 13.2 |
2006 | 18,046.76 | 15.5 |
2007 | 23,397.13 | 17.5 |
2008 | 26,696.84 | 19.7 |
2009 | 34,606.23 | 21.1 |
2010 | 42,996.48 | 22.3 |
2011 | 44,491.28 | 21.6 |
2012 | 51,028.41 | 20.8 |
From the most recent data, we expect that returns on investment will gradually fall but will stay at a level high enough to attract investment. Based on this, we forecast that investment in physical capital will continue to grow at a rapid pace in the near term.
Many economists worry that the PRC's economic growth relies too heavily on saving and investment. They posit that a large contribution of capital means a small contribution to technological progress, a condition that may not be sustainable. However, none of the existing methods measuring technological progress has successfully accounted for the technological progress embedded in capital. Capital investment brings about new approaches of production as well as new teams of workers, which together increase productivity and bolster growth. There may also be a time lag between capital investment and the functioning of capital stock.
The potential role of physical capital in development depends on the relationship between investment and technical progress. Scholars working on growth, especially those focusing on technology diffusion and TFP, have been studying this potential role. Caselli and Wilson (2004) found strikingly large differences in investment composition across countries, with the composition of capital accounting for large observed differences in TFP across countries. They also found that the differences were based on each equipment type's degree of complementarity with other factors whose abundance differs across countries (Caselli and Coleman 2001).
Comin and Hobijin (2004) observed a trickle-down mechanism in the diffusion of technologies across countries, which meant that although most of the technologies originating from advanced economies were adopted there first, other countries that lag economically could still benefit subsequently. The determinants of the speed at which a country adopts technologies include the country's human capital endowment, type of government, degree of openness to trade, and adoption of predecessor technologies.
Jorgenson and Vu (2010) introduced a new framework for projecting the potential growth of the world economy, emphasizing the contribution of information technology. Investment in information and communications technology (ICT) raises the amount of capital available for labor, thus increasing labor productivity, likely increasing economic growth. It also introduces new technologies into the production process.
Inklaar and Timmer (2013) discuss new measures of capital stocks in PWT version 8.0, while Aghion (2014) notes the positive relation between ICT share (in value-added) and economic growth, using panel data. The contribution of investment in ICT has increased in all regions of the world, but especially in industrialized economies and developing Asia.
To explore the sustainability of the PRC's future growth in physical capital investment based on the composition of capital, we collected data on the growth of ICT capital services. Data show that ICT capital services grew at a more rapid pace in the country than in Japan, the Republic of Korea, and the US during 2000–2013 (Table 7).
. | . | . | Republic . | . |
---|---|---|---|---|
. | PRC . | Japan . | of Korea . | US . |
2000 | 28.73 | 6.62 | 20.07 | 18.44 |
2001 | 26.44 | 7.24 | 17.30 | 13.86 |
2002 | 24.90 | 6.74 | 10.75 | 8.12 |
2003 | 24.48 | 5.27 | 6.13 | 5.94 |
2004 | 25.78 | 5.64 | 3.39 | 6.59 |
2005 | 26.46 | 4.76 | 4.62 | 7.31 |
2006 | 25.17 | 3.30 | 7.27 | 8.06 |
2007 | 22.06 | 3.69 | 8.93 | 9.19 |
2008 | 20.92 | 5.62 | 8.32 | 9.00 |
2009 | 19.71 | 7.84 | 6.39 | 6.59 |
2010 | 17.18 | 8.66 | 6.05 | 5.10 |
2011 | 15.52 | 8.94 | 7.87 | 5.58 |
2012 | 15.82 | 9.89 | 9.42 | 6.87 |
2013 | 17.39 | 10.73 | 10.50 | 8.21 |
. | . | . | Republic . | . |
---|---|---|---|---|
. | PRC . | Japan . | of Korea . | US . |
2000 | 28.73 | 6.62 | 20.07 | 18.44 |
2001 | 26.44 | 7.24 | 17.30 | 13.86 |
2002 | 24.90 | 6.74 | 10.75 | 8.12 |
2003 | 24.48 | 5.27 | 6.13 | 5.94 |
2004 | 25.78 | 5.64 | 3.39 | 6.59 |
2005 | 26.46 | 4.76 | 4.62 | 7.31 |
2006 | 25.17 | 3.30 | 7.27 | 8.06 |
2007 | 22.06 | 3.69 | 8.93 | 9.19 |
2008 | 20.92 | 5.62 | 8.32 | 9.00 |
2009 | 19.71 | 7.84 | 6.39 | 6.59 |
2010 | 17.18 | 8.66 | 6.05 | 5.10 |
2011 | 15.52 | 8.94 | 7.87 | 5.58 |
2012 | 15.82 | 9.89 | 9.42 | 6.87 |
2013 | 17.39 | 10.73 | 10.50 | 8.21 |
ICT = information and communications technology, PRC = People's Republic of China, US = United States.
Source: The Conference Board Total Economy Database. Available online at: http://www.conference-board.org/data/economydatabase/ (accessed January 2014).
This suggests that the potential exists for further increases in productivity and capital investment in the PRC in the near future. The average annual contribution of ICT capital services to overall growth in capital services in the country was 1.06 percentage points from 2004 to 2013, compared with 5.57 percentage points for non-ICT capital services during the same period.
In addition to rapid physical capital accumulation, the PRC has seen large-scale human capital accumulation. The country has been improving its stock of human capital over the past 30 years, owing to government commitment and increasing returns to education. Education spending by the Chinese government in terms of the share of total government spending is lower than that in the US but higher than in the United Kingdom and Japan (Bai, Wang, and Qian 2010).
Higher education in the PRC has grown at a faster pace than both primary and secondary education. College admission and enrollment has increased tenfold, with 6.4 million bachelor's and 514,000 master's and PhD degree holders produced by Chinese universities in 2013 (Table 8). The quality of human capital investment in the country has also improved through the years. The number of college students graduating as a percentage of the total has risen in the 2010s compared to the 1990s.
. | . | . | MA and PhD/ . |
---|---|---|---|
. | College . | MA and PhD . | Undergraduates (%) . |
1991 | 614.0 | 32.5 | 5.0 |
1995 | 805.0 | 31.9 | 3.8 |
2000 | 949.8 | 58.8 | 5.8 |
2005 | 3068.0 | 189.7 | 5.8 |
2013 | 6,387.2 | 514.0 | 7.4 |
. | . | . | MA and PhD/ . |
---|---|---|---|
. | College . | MA and PhD . | Undergraduates (%) . |
1991 | 614.0 | 32.5 | 5.0 |
1995 | 805.0 | 31.9 | 3.8 |
2000 | 949.8 | 58.8 | 5.8 |
2005 | 3068.0 | 189.7 | 5.8 |
2013 | 6,387.2 | 514.0 | 7.4 |
MA = Master of Arts, PhD = Doctor of Philosophy.
PRC = People's Republic of China.
Table 9 similarly shows that the number of graduates from college and senior secondary schools in the PRC has increased dramatically in recent years. This trend, which has greatly improved the country's quality of education, is expected to continue in the near future. As Aghion (2014) and other authors have pointed out, education is important in bolstering economic growth.
. | . | Regular Senior . | Secondary . | Junior . | Regular . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Regular . | Secondary . | Vocational . | Secondary . | Primary . |
. | College . | Schools . | Education . | School . | School . |
1978 | 0.165 | 6.827 | 22.879 | ||
1990 | 0.614 | 2.330 | 11.230 | 18.631 | |
2000 | 0.950 | 3.015 | 16.335 | 24.192 | |
2010 | 5.754 | 7.944 | 6.653 | 17.504 | 17.396 |
2012 | 6.247 | 7.915 | 6.749 | 16.608 | 16.416 |
2013 | 6.387 | 7.990 | 15.811 |
. | . | Regular Senior . | Secondary . | Junior . | Regular . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Regular . | Secondary . | Vocational . | Secondary . | Primary . |
. | College . | Schools . | Education . | School . | School . |
1978 | 0.165 | 6.827 | 22.879 | ||
1990 | 0.614 | 2.330 | 11.230 | 18.631 | |
2000 | 0.950 | 3.015 | 16.335 | 24.192 | |
2010 | 5.754 | 7.944 | 6.653 | 17.504 | 17.396 |
2012 | 6.247 | 7.915 | 6.749 | 16.608 | 16.416 |
2013 | 6.387 | 7.990 | 15.811 |
Source: National Bureau of Statistics. 2014. China Statistical Yearbook 2014. Beijing: China Statistics Press. Tables 20–9.
Period . | (%) . |
---|---|
1985–1989 | 27 |
1990–1994 | 17 |
1995–1999 | 15 |
2000–2004 | 20 |
2005–2009 | 19 |
1985–2009 | 19 |
Period . | (%) . |
---|---|
1985–1989 | 27 |
1990–1994 | 17 |
1995–1999 | 15 |
2000–2004 | 20 |
2005–2009 | 19 |
1985–2009 | 19 |
Source: Xie and Zhang 2014.
C. Structural Readjustment
The PRC has been experiencing structural changes in the past 3 decades. Structural readjustment, which allows a transfer of resources from sectors with lower productivity to sectors with higher productivity, serves as another source of economic growth.
Brandt, Hsieh, and Zhu (2008) decomposed the PRC's growth according to agriculture and non-agriculture sources during 1978–2004 and found that labor reallocation from agriculture to non-agriculture contributed 24.6% to the country's overall growth. They attribute this to the large productivity gap between agriculture and non-agriculture sectors during the period.
Theoretically, GDP growth in a multisector model can be divided into four components—the contributions of capital, labor, pure technical progress (weighted average of technical progress in all sectors), and structural change.
The current Chinese economy is still far from its long-term steady state. Large productivity gaps still exist between sectors of the economy, while endowments continue to change as income rises. The production structure clearly needs to change to follow the changes in endowments. These structural readjustments should be able to provide new sources of economic growth and raise the potential for a relatively high growth rate in the medium to long run.
Heterogeneity at the firm level is a source of productivity growth. Aghion (2014) points out that the heterogeneity between firms is much larger than that between sector averages. In the US, the productivity of the top 10% most productive firms is twice that of the bottom 10%. Hsieh and Klenow (2009) find the corresponding multiple to be as high as 5 times in the PRC. This huge difference shows the country's potential for structural improvements in the future.
The enormous size of the Chinese economy benefits structural readjustment, as a wide enough industrial spectrum makes an update of the industrial structure and a widening of product variety possible. The huge product space makes it possible for the country to upgrade its industrial structure at a wide scale. This feature differentiates the PRC from mid-sized countries such as Japan and the Republic of Korea.
Aside from well-functioning markets and continued structural upgrading, there are other factors that contribute to the structural improvement of the Chinese economy and that help drive future growth. These include private sector development and privatization of state-owned enterprises to spur greater competition, greater protection of intellectual property rights and other legal support to encourage R&D and innovation in the manufacturing sector, bilateral investment treaties and free trade zones to foster greater openness of the economy, and deregulation and introduction of greater competition to improve productivity in the services sector.
Innovation is a key driver of long-run growth, one that is particularly important for middle-income countries such as the PRC. Xie and Zhang (2014) find that domestic Chinese firms have become increasingly more innovative in terms of patent applications, and that private firms, rather than state-owned firms, have been the engine of innovation. Facing increasing wages, the firms have had to invest more in technologies to substitute the more expensive labor. The annual growth rate of patents granted during 1985–2012 averaged at 19%, almost twice the annual growth rate of GDP during the same period (Xie and Zhang 2014).
Overall, on one hand, the PRC is still far behind the world technology frontier and will continue to enjoy the advantage of backwardness. On the other hand, it is closer to the world technology frontier than at any time previously and possesses greater capital and skilled labor than it did 30 years ago. This provides a basis for updating industries and further economic development.
V. Preconditions for the PRC's Sustained Growth and Policy Suggestions
The PRC has the potential to sustain a relatively high growth rate in the long run provided government adopts the right policies. There are a number of general preconditions or prerequisites that must be met in order to achieve this goal.
The PRC needs to narrow income disparities and fight corruption to maintain social stability. Greater income disparity and corruption are the results of the dual-track transition strategy where the government continues to provide subsidies and protection to nonviable firms in prioritized capital-intensive sectors, creating distortions in factor markets and monopolies in certain service sectors while allowing or facilitating the entry of new firms to the labor-intensive sector that had been previously repressed. Such an approach allows the country to achieve stability and dynamic growth simultaneously.
However, distortions in factor markets and monopolies in telecommunications and financial sectors create rents and encourage rent-seeking, leading to greater income disparity and corruption. Many capital-intensive firms in the old prioritized sectors have become viable because of the change in the endowment structure, which was a consequence of rapid growth and capital accumulation over the past 35 years. It is time for the country to eliminate these distortions and complete the transition to a well-functioning market economy, allowing prices to play a decisive role in resource allocation to improve efficiency and eliminate the root of income disparity and corruption (Lin 2012a).
The PRC needs to continue investing in physical and human capital in order to change its endowment structure. It also needs to continue upgrading technologies, transforming its industrial structure, and tapping latecomer advantages. As developments continue, factor endowments and industrial structure will keep changing, and the country will need to update its infrastructure accordingly. The inconsistency between the two means leaving the equilibrium path and lowering trend growth.
Finally, the Chinese government also needs to play an enabling role in future economic development. It needs to help firms reduce transaction costs by improving both soft and hard infrastructure. A sound fiscal position, at both central and local government levels, will be beneficial to economic growth. An enabling government is also essential to overcome inherent externalities of technological innovation and industrial upgrading. State effort is also needed to improve the country's environmental quality and achieve environmental sustainability.
VI. Concluding Remarks
In sum, the PRC can sustain a relatively high growth path over a long period based on three basic arguments. First, since a substantial technological gap still exists between the PRC and major developed countries, it can continue to enjoy the advantage of backwardness. Second, the long period of large-scale infrastructure investment that began several decades ago can still continue and provide the country a basis for further growth. Third, structural readjustment, which is needed in many fields, should be able to bolster economic growth in the long run. These arguments are supported by growth accounting analysis.
We argue that to realize the potential for sustained growth, a number of general preconditions or prerequisites need to be fulfilled. These include well-functioning markets, an appropriate rate of investment, continued structural upgrading, and an enabling government that can facilitate the appropriate structural transformation. If the economic adjustments are done correctly and in a timely manner, sustained growth should be possible in the medium- and long-term.
References*
Notes
These include Paul Krugman in his columns (e.g., Hitting China's Wall, New York Times, 18 July 2013) and Nouriel Roubini in his articles (e.g., China's Bad Growth Bet, Project Syndicate, 14 April 2011). Others who have commented on the issue include John Aziz (Is China's Economy Headed for a Crash? The Week, 13 January 2014), Nathan Bell (How to Prepare for a China Crash, The Age, 24 September 2012), Vitaliy Katsenelson (How China Will Crash and Burn, Forbes, 6 July 2011), and John Mauldin (The Only Question about the China Crash is When, Business Insider, 24 November 2010). Some observers point to the collapse of the PRC as the biggest risk to the world economy, for instance, as articulated by George Soros in one of his articles (e.g., The World Economy's Shifting Challenges, Project Syndicate, 2 January 2014). In these articles, ADB recognizes China as the People's Republic of China.
ADB recognizes “China” as the People's Republic of China.
Author notes
The authors thank ADB for organizing the symposium, the referees for useful comments, and Qingqing Chen for her research assistance.