Previous studies have focused on when the renminbi will play a significant role as an international currency, but less attention has been paid to where. We fill this gap by contrasting two answers to the question. One is that the renminbi will assume the role of a global currency similar to the U.S. dollar. Supporters point to China's widely diversified trade and financial flows and to its institutional initiatives, not just in Asia but around the world. The other is that the renminbi will play a regional role in Asia equivalent to that of the euro in Greater Europe. Proponents of this view argue that China has a natural advantage in leveraging regional supply chains and deepening its links with other Asian countries as well as in developing regional institutions. Asia, they argue on these grounds, will become the natural habitat for the renminbi.

Although much has been written about when China's currency, the renminbi (RMB), will assume an international role, less attention has been paid to the question of where. One view is that the renminbi will eventually challenge the dollar as the leading global currency. Supporting theories posit that network effects are strong, meaning that if it pays for banks, firms, and governments in some countries to do business in renminbi then it will pay for banks, firms, and governments in other countries to do so as well, regardless of where they are located. Supporting evidence includes the fact that China engages in merchandise and commodity trade with economies in every part of the world, as befits its position as the largest national exporter. China similarly makes direct foreign investments in every region. From these observations flows the conclusion that the renminbi will ultimately come to rival the U.S. dollar as a global currency.

The alternative is that the renminbi is destined to be a leading regional currency, in Asia in particular. Its future international role, in this case, will more closely resemble that of the euro than the dollar. The euro is used as an international unit of account, means of payment and store of value, primarily in Europe's neighborhood—in European countries as well as non-euro area members and countries to Europe's immediate east and south. Empirical studies confirm that the influence of geographical distance on international trade remains significant, reflecting transportation costs, broadly defined.1 More strikingly, geographical distance also matters for financial transactions, reflecting the cost and difficulty of acquiring and disseminating information across space. Given how use of a currency in cross-border transactions flows from the geography of those transactions, this implies a bias toward the use of a given currency unit in the economic neighborhood of its national issuer. Similar to the role of the euro in Greater Europe, it follows that Asia is the natural region in which the renminbi will come to act as an international currency.

Consistent with this observation, the first seven countries to establish mechanisms for direct trading of their currencies against the renminbi—rather than buying and selling dollars as an intermediate step toward acquiring and disposing of the Chinese currency—were Asian countries. Efforts to foster renminbi internationalization have also relied heavily on developing transactions with an offshore financial center, Hong Kong, whose prominence reflects precisely its location in Asia. These reflections suggest that the renminbi will come to play an important role mainly in the region.

Political scientists (e.g., Helleiner and Korschner 2014) argue that the decision to use a currency in cross-border transactions reflects not just economic links with the issuer but also the latter's ability to project political leverage and power. The dollar has an important role, these analysts observe, in regions where the United States has political influence. China is best able to project leverage and power in the South China Sea and elsewhere in in the Asia-Pacific region, lacking as it does the aircraft carriers and allies needed to project them over longer distances, at least to an equivalent extent. Again, the conclusion follows that the renminbi's future is as a regional currency for Asia more than as a global currency in the same manner as the dollar.

The rebuttal is that the tyranny of distance is declining with improvements in transportation and information technologies. It may be true that the first seven countries to establish direct trading in renminbi were in Asia, but a growing number of countries in other parts of the world have followed suit. Hong Kong's special status as an offshore renminbi center is now being challenged by newly established centers from Singapore and Frankfurt to London and Toronto. This trend is likely to continue as China relaxes restrictions on use of the renminbi and opens its capital account.

Our goal in this paper is to evaluate these two views of the renminbi's prospective role as an international unit of account, means of payment, and store of value for private and official transactions. We begin in Section 2 with a review of the theory and history of international currencies. In Sections 3 and 4 we then develop the cases for a global and regional role for the renminbi, respectively. Our conclusions, in Section 5, are mixed, reflecting the fact that this paper has not only two views but also two authors.

Eichengreen (2014) distinguishes two classes of models of international currency status. One class (examples of which include Krugman [1980, 1984] and Matsuyama, Kiyotaki, and Matsui [1993]) emphasizes the power of network effects in the international monetary domain. Because of the importance of network-increasing returns, once a currency is adopted for international transactions, it comes to be used widely. In these models, it pays to do international business in the same currency that one's counterparties use in their own international transactions, including in transactions with third parties.

These network-increasing returns can neutralize other disadvantages of using a potential international currency—for example, such that the central bank issuing it and therefore acting as liquidity provider of last resort of the currency is in a different region and time zone. From this it follows that once a currency is used in international transactions in some countries; it will come to be used globally. Other implications include the fact that first-mover advantage is powerful, that persistence is strong, and that international currency status may be a natural monopoly. Many of these theoretical analyses are motivated by the desire to understand the international role of the U.S. dollar, which is used as an international unit of account, means of payment, and store of value globally and not merely, say, in the Western Hemisphere.

The alternative (“new”) view of international currency status does not deny the existence of network-increasing returns but builds on theoretical work on open systems (see, e.g., Farrell and Klemperer 2007). In this view, increasing returns may exist but are not large, and interchangeability costs in high-tech 21st century financial markets are no longer so high. By implication, it is possible to have low transaction costs as well as stable and predictable prices in cross-border transactions in several national currencies. It follows that other modest advantages (that the liquidity provider of last resort of a currency is in the same time zone or that there are other benefits of proximity, for example) may, too, be determining factors in the decision by a bank, firm, or government regarding which currencies to use for international transactions. In this class of models, multiple currencies can play a role in the international domain, with different units being used by different counterparties, including in different locations, as a function of local or regional characteristics.

Proponents of both views draw support from history. Those who subscribe to the old view, point to the dominance of specific currencies in international transactions at different points in time: the pound sterling before 1914 and the U.S. dollar after 1945. Their analyses highlight how these currencies were widely used in cross-border transactions around the world. They emphasize evidence of persistence or “lock-in” with the currencies in question continuing to play global roles even after the share of the issuing country's currency in international transactions had peaked, consistent with a setting in which network increasing returns are strong.

Advocates of the alternative (“new”) view argue that a closer look reveals that there has always been more than one consequential international currency at a given point in time, and that the use of different currencies has typically had a regional dimension. Lindert's (1969) study showed that the foreign exchange reserves of central banks and governments in 1900 and 1913 were divided between the British sterling, the French franc, and the German mark. Building on Lindert's work, Eichengreen and Flandreau (1996) describe how the mark was held and used mainly in Eastern and Southeastern Europe as well as in parts of Scandinavia, whereas the franc was used in Western European countries like Spain, Belgium, and Switzerland, and the sterling dominated in Latin America and in the British Commonwealth and Empire.

Eichengreen and Flandreau (2009) provide a parallel analysis of the 1920s and 1930s. They find that the sterling and the U.S. dollar both featured prominently in the reserve portfolios of central banks and governments, with the sterling playing an important role in Scandinavia (having by this time displaced the German mark), Portugal, and other European members of the so-called sterling area and, as before, in the British Commonwealth and Empire, while the dollar took on a growing role in other parts of the world, including Latin America. That there were shifts relative to the pre-World War I position, with Scandinavia moving into sterling's camp and the dollar being utilized more widely in Latin America, poses a challenge to the traditional view emphasizing lock-in and persistence. Extrapolated to the future, this suggests that there may be greater scope for relatively rapid adoption of the renminbi for cross-border transactions in Asia than globally.

Another literature examines the use of international currencies during and after the Bretton Woods period. Some authors such as Bergsten (1975) suggest that the Bretton Woods system is properly viewed as a tripartite structure consisting of three blocs based on the sterling, the dollar, and gold. The interwar and wartime sterling area persisted, while the rest of the world coalesced into gold and dollar blocs. Members of the dollar area (Brazil, Canada, Israel, Japan, Mexico, Norway, Saudi Arabia, Sweden, Thailand, Turkey, Venezuela, Germany from 1967 and Spain from 1970) took the bulk of their exchange earnings in dollars. Members of the gold bloc, in contrast, took fully 75 percent of their increased reserves in the form of gold in the 1960s. The core members of this post-World War II gold bloc—Belgium, France, Italy, the Netherlands, and Switzerland—were not only geographically contiguous but had also been core members of the gold bloc of the 1930s and, indeed, key members of the 19th-century Latin Monetary Union.

Others, like McKinnon (1979), argue that the dollar was the dominant international vehicle and reserve currency in transactions among banks and the primary currency of invoice in international commodity trade throughout this period. They refer not to the Bretton Woods and post-Bretton Woods systems but to the “gold-dollar system” through the early 1970s and the “dollar” or “limping-dollar standard” thereafter. Members of this school (e.g., Prasad 2014) emphasize the extent to which the international monetary and financial system is still heavily dollar-based even today. Goldberg and Tille (2005) show that the dollar's use in invoicing international merchandise transactions remains far in excess of the U.S. share of global merchandise trade. The dollar is used in 85 percent of global foreign exchange transactions, far in excess of the United States’ share of global cross-border financial transactions. And the dollar continues to constitute more than 60 percent of global identified foreign exchange reserves despite the fact that the United States’ share of GDP is no more than 25 percent.

These observations are consistent with strong network-increasing returns, in the manner of traditional models in which a single national currency dominates international transactions. In the extreme, the implication of this view emphasizing dollar dominance is that for the renminbi to become a true international currency, it will not only have to supplant the dollar, but will also have to do so globally. The rebuttal is that the Bretton Woods and post-Bretton Woods periods were special by virtue of the absence of viable alternatives to the dollar. That is, the dollar was by default the dominant international currency, as no other national unit possessed the scale, stability, and liquidity needed to render it attractive for widespread cross-border use. This is something that will now change, it is hypothesized, as the renminbi acquires the stability and liquidity required to assume a consequential international role.

If this hypothesis is correct, then the dollar and the renminbi may eventually coexist in the international domain. The question is whether they will both be used globally, in cross-border transactions with counterparties around the world, or mainly in different regions: the renminbi in Asia and the dollar in other parts of the world.

There is no one-to-one mapping between, on the one hand, trade and financial transactions with a country, and, on the other hand, the likelihood of using its currency as an international unit of account, means of payment, and store of value. But studies establishing this fact also establish a positive association between the two tendencies: more extensive economic relations with a country increase the likelihood of using its currency in cross-border transactions. This is not surprising given that firms, banks, and other entities in a country will have a natural preference for using their domestic currency in cross-border transactions, in turn conferring on their foreign counterparties an incentive to accommodate that preference. Goldberg and Tille (2005) document this for the choice of currency for invoicing merchandise transactions. The earlier literature has similarly shown that trade and financial transactions with a country, the use of its national unit to settle those transactions, and the need to hold these currencies in foreign reserves all go together.

It is therefore relevant to observe that China's foreign trade and financial transactions are widely distributed across regions. Figures 1 and 2 show the geographical distribution of China's imports and exports. Only one-quarter of China's exports go to other Asian countries, excluding Hong Kong, Macao, and Taiwan; an additional 24 percent go to Europe, and 23 percent to North America. The regional composition of China's imports is more concentrated, but only slightly, with one-third of the total drawn from other Asian countries. This difference on the import side reflects China's role in global supply chains, where large volumes of intermediate goods from Asia (industrial materials, parts and components, and semi-finished goods, for example) are imported to be processed for subsequent export (Choi 2015).

Figure 1.

Regional composition of China's exports, 2013

Figure 1.

Regional composition of China's exports, 2013

Close modal
Figure 2.

Regional composition of China's imports, 2013

Figure 2.

Regional composition of China's imports, 2013

Close modal

At first glance, the direction of China's foreign direct investment, depicted in Figure 3, is more concentrated, with the majority destined for Hong Kong, Macao, and Taiwan. But these offshore centers are serving mainly as intermediaries for Chinese foreign investment ultimately destined for other countries. Excluding offshore centers, Chinese foreign investment is widely distributed. This reflects investments by Chinese enterprises in commodity- and energy-related sectors as well as manufacturing.

Figure 3.

Regional composition of China's overseas direct investment, 2013

Figure 3.

Regional composition of China's overseas direct investment, 2013

Close modal

Likewise, China's free trade agreements (FTAs) reflect its geographically diversified trade and investment flows. Although the country's early FTAs were with countries in Asia (ASEAN in 2004, Pakistan in 2006, Singapore in 2008), China has since negotiated agreements with countries in other parts of the world (including, to date, Chile, Peru, Costa Rica, Iceland, and Switzerland; see Table 1). FTAs under discussion or likely to be under discussion in the future suggest that this geographically diversified approach to negotiations will persist.

Table 1. 
Existing and prospective FTAs
CountryDate
Bilateral FTAs  
Developing countries  
Pakistan November 2006 
Chile November 2005 
Peru April 2009 
Costa Rica April 2010 
Developed countries  
New Zealand April 2008 
Singapore October 2008 
Iceland April 2013 
Switzerland July 2013 
South Korea June 2015 
Australia June 2015 
Multilateral FTAs  
ASEAN November 2004 
FTA under negotiation  
Gulf Cooperation Council July 2004 
Regional Comprehensive Partnership May 2013 
ASEAN FTA Upgrade September 2014 
Norway September 2008 
Japan and Korea January 2013 
Sri Lanka September 2014 
Maldives September 2015 
Georgia December 2015 
FTA under consideration 2003 
India N/A 
ColombiaMoldova N/A 
Fiji N/A 
Nepal March 2016 
CountryDate
Bilateral FTAs  
Developing countries  
Pakistan November 2006 
Chile November 2005 
Peru April 2009 
Costa Rica April 2010 
Developed countries  
New Zealand April 2008 
Singapore October 2008 
Iceland April 2013 
Switzerland July 2013 
South Korea June 2015 
Australia June 2015 
Multilateral FTAs  
ASEAN November 2004 
FTA under negotiation  
Gulf Cooperation Council July 2004 
Regional Comprehensive Partnership May 2013 
ASEAN FTA Upgrade September 2014 
Norway September 2008 
Japan and Korea January 2013 
Sri Lanka September 2014 
Maldives September 2015 
Georgia December 2015 
FTA under consideration 2003 
India N/A 
ColombiaMoldova N/A 
Fiji N/A 
Nepal March 2016 

Source: Whalley and Li (2014), China, Ministry of Commerce (2015).

With the growth of China's trade and financial links comes an incentive to conduct transactions in renminbi. In turn, this creates an incentive to stabilize a trade partner's local currency against the renminbi, which encourages the central banks of these countries to hold renminbi-denominated foreign exchange reserves and establish contingent renminbi liquidity lines with the People's Bank of China (PBOC). But is this last tendency limited mainly to Asia, or is it observed more widely? To address this issue, Subramanian and Kessler (2013) estimated “Frankel and Wei regressions,” where the value of the local currency against a numeraire, in this case the Swiss franc, is taken as a function of the renminbi/franc, dollar/franc, yen/franc, and euro/franc rates. We update their results for a sample of 41 countries, as shown in Table 2 for the period January 2013 to January 2016 (as well as for the July 2012–July 2015 period). Specifically, we estimate:
1
where denotes the change in the log of currency X (the U.S. dollar, the yuan, the euro, and the Japanese yen) all against the Swiss franc. The dominant reference currency in Table 2 is then taken as the currency with the largest effect on the exchange rate of the countries considered.
Table 2. 
Dominant reference currency by region (2013–16)
RMBUSDEuro
Asia 
Europe 
Middle East and Africa 
North America 
South America 
Total 11 17 12 
RMBUSDEuro
Asia 
Europe 
Middle East and Africa 
North America 
South America 
Total 11 17 12 

As one would expect, we find the dollar to be the dominant reference currency for many countries throughout the Americas, Asia, Europe, and the Middle East. The euro tends to be the dominant reference currency mainly for European countries. Interestingly, the renminbi is the second most dominant reference currency in Asia, and in particular for the ASEAN economies.2

In addition to having the strongest effect in a number of Asian countries, the renminbi also has a significant effect in several South American countries and a statistically significant effect in a number of European countries as well.3 The renminbi tends to be important for the other BRICS members (Brazil, Russia, India and South Africa) as well as for countries elsewhere such as Israel, Mexico, and Peru.

Table 3 shows that the weight on the renminbi is plausibly a function of commercial and financial links between a given country and China—links that are as much global as regional. Following Subramanian and Kessler (2013), we relate the coefficient on the renminbi/Swiss franc exchange rate in the preceding equation to bilateral trade with China, the similarity of inflation rates, and common financial shocks:
Common inflation shocks are measured as the correlation between a country's monthly inflation rate and that of China during the period January 2012–December 2014, and common financial shocks are then taken as the correlation between a country's reference stock market index daily returns and the Shanghai Stock Exchange A Share Index daily returns over the July 2012–October 2014 period. The data correspond to the sample in Subramanian and Kessler (2013). Both the inflation figures and the stock index return figures are logged. The share of trade is measured as the proportion of a country's imports from China relative to the imports from the rest of the world. This figure is taken as the average import ratios for 2012–13.
Table 3. 
Determinants of renminbi weight (2013–16)
RMBCoef.Robust Std. Err.tP > |t|[95% Conf.Interval]
Financial 1.694931 0.5871824 2.89 0.007 0.4973646 2.892497 
Inflation −0.2414102 0.1520255 −1.59 0.122 −0.5514683 0.0686479 
Import share −1.310916 0.8483331 −1.55 0.132 −3.041103 0.4192707 
Constant 0.1651439 0.0924021 1.79 0.084 −0.023315 0.3535993 
RMBCoef.Robust Std. Err.tP > |t|[95% Conf.Interval]
Financial 1.694931 0.5871824 2.89 0.007 0.4973646 2.892497 
Inflation −0.2414102 0.1520255 −1.59 0.122 −0.5514683 0.0686479 
Import share −1.310916 0.8483331 −1.55 0.132 −3.041103 0.4192707 
Constant 0.1651439 0.0924021 1.79 0.084 −0.023315 0.3535993 

Number of obs = 35

F(3, 31) = 3.48

Prob > F = 0.0275

R2 = 0.02678

Root MSE = 0.2553

In Table 3, the coefficient of a country's financial shock is positive and statistically significant at the 10 percent confidence level. Thus, we observe a larger renminbi co-movement from a higher correlation for a country's financial market with China, controlling for inflation and trade. Evidently, the coefficients for inflation shocks and trade shares, although negative, do not seem to affect the renminbi co-movement for the sample countries’ exchange rates.

The question of whether the renminbi's future is mainly as a regional or global currency should be addressed from an institutional perspective as well. Beijing has used the China Development Bank and Export-Import Bank of China, for example, to promote renminbi-denominated lending and settlement. Countries to which these institutions lend receive funds in renminbi, which they then use to finance imports from China and to purchase the services of Chinese construction companies. Although a significant share of the lending by these state banks is to other Asian countries, a non-negligible share is to countries and companies outside of the region (to the government of Venezuela in 2010, for example, and to small- and medium-size enterprises in a variety of African countries).

China has recently sponsored the creation of the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB) to promote infrastructure investment in the Asia-Pacific region and, not incidentally, to create business for Chinese construction companies. Although the AIIB's current objective is to contribute to Asian infrastructure development and regional integration, membership is global, not regional, with 57 prospective founding members at the time of writing. These include 24 countries in Asia, 20 in Europe, and 9 in the Middle East (see Table 4). These countries will all be contributing capital to the bank, and their construction companies and consultants will similarly be competing for business. It will not be surprising, therefore, to see the AIIB expand its operations to developing countries outside of Asia.

Table 4. 
Founding members of the AIIB
East Asia and Pacific (12) 
Bruneia, Cambodia, Chinaa, Indonesiaa, Laosa, Malaysia, Mongoliaa, Philippines, Republic of Koreaa, Singaporea
Thailand, Vietnam 
Other Asia (12) 
Azerbaijan, Bangladesh, Indiaa, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyz Republic, Maldivesa, Myanmara, Nepala, Pakistana, Sri Lanka, 
Tajikistan, Uzbekistan 
Oceania (2) 
Australiaa, New Zealanda 
Middle East (9) 
Egypt, Iran, Israela, Jordana, Kuwait, Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabiaa, United Arab Emiratesa 
Western Europe (15) 
Austriaa, Denmarka, Finlanda, France, Germanya, Iceland, Italy, Luxembourga, Netherlandsa, Norwaya, Poland, 
Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdoma 
Other Europe (5) 
Georgiaa, Maltaa, Poland, Russiaa, Turkey 
South America (1) 
Brazil 
Africa (1) 
South Africa 
East Asia and Pacific (12) 
Bruneia, Cambodia, Chinaa, Indonesiaa, Laosa, Malaysia, Mongoliaa, Philippines, Republic of Koreaa, Singaporea
Thailand, Vietnam 
Other Asia (12) 
Azerbaijan, Bangladesh, Indiaa, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyz Republic, Maldivesa, Myanmara, Nepala, Pakistana, Sri Lanka, 
Tajikistan, Uzbekistan 
Oceania (2) 
Australiaa, New Zealanda 
Middle East (9) 
Egypt, Iran, Israela, Jordana, Kuwait, Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabiaa, United Arab Emiratesa 
Western Europe (15) 
Austriaa, Denmarka, Finlanda, France, Germanya, Iceland, Italy, Luxembourga, Netherlandsa, Norwaya, Poland, 
Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdoma 
Other Europe (5) 
Georgiaa, Maltaa, Poland, Russiaa, Turkey 
South America (1) 
Brazil 
Africa (1) 
South Africa 

Source: AIIB.org

Note: a. Instrument of ratification is accepted.

Other institutional bases for wider international use of the renminbi include swap lines with the PBOC, the designation of a Chinese financial institution as official clearing bank for settling renminbi-denominated transactions, and a quota for investing in China's local-currency equity market (a renminbi-qualified foreign institutional investor [RQFII] quota). Weir (2015) refers to these initiatives as the “three gifts,” because they require negotiation and agreement with the Chinese authorities and because they tend to go together. They represent implicit endorsement by the Chinese authorities of a center's offshore RMB status.

In practice, these arrangements extend beyond Asia. Table 5 lists offshore clearing banks in foreign financial centers by date of establishment. These centers now include many cities outside of Asia and across the globe, including Frankfurt, London, Paris, Sydney, and Toronto. Indeed, virtually every important financial hub is now a designated renminbi offshore center with the exception of New York. If we exclude Hong Kong, Macau, and Taipei, which played strategic roles in the early development of the offshore renminbi market, only four Asian cities are designated offshore renminbi centers, compared with four in Europe and three in the rest of the world. In terms of geographic distribution, there is no obvious bias favoring Asia.

Table 5. 
Offshore RMB centers
CountryCityDateBank
China SAR Hong Kong 2003.12 Bank of China 
China SAR Macau 2004.08 Bank of China 
Taiwan Taipei 2012.12 Bank of China 
Singapore Singapore 2013.04 Industrial and Commercial Bank of China 
United Kingdom London 2014.06 China Construction Bank 
Germany Frankfurt 2014.06 Bank of China 
South Korea Seoul 2014.07 Bank of Communications 
France Paris 2014.09 Bank of China 
Luxembourg Luxembourg 2014.09 Industrial and Commercial Bank of China 
Qatar Doha 2014.11 Industrial and Commercial Bank of China 
Canada Toronto, Vancouver 2014.11 Industrial and Commercial Bank of China 
Malaysia Kuala Lumpur 2014.11 Bank of China 
Australia Sydney 2014.11 Bank of China 
Thailand Bangkok 2015.01 Industrial and Commercial Bank of China 
CountryCityDateBank
China SAR Hong Kong 2003.12 Bank of China 
China SAR Macau 2004.08 Bank of China 
Taiwan Taipei 2012.12 Bank of China 
Singapore Singapore 2013.04 Industrial and Commercial Bank of China 
United Kingdom London 2014.06 China Construction Bank 
Germany Frankfurt 2014.06 Bank of China 
South Korea Seoul 2014.07 Bank of Communications 
France Paris 2014.09 Bank of China 
Luxembourg Luxembourg 2014.09 Industrial and Commercial Bank of China 
Qatar Doha 2014.11 Industrial and Commercial Bank of China 
Canada Toronto, Vancouver 2014.11 Industrial and Commercial Bank of China 
Malaysia Kuala Lumpur 2014.11 Bank of China 
Australia Sydney 2014.11 Bank of China 
Thailand Bangkok 2015.01 Industrial and Commercial Bank of China 

Source: Bloomberg, Bank of China, Industrial and Commercial Bank of China, MAS, People's Bank of China, Reuters, UK government data, Wall Street Journal.

Having an official clearing bank matters because access to the renminbi is limited, since access to Chinese financial markets is limited. This designation creates a presumption that the bank in question will clear transactions in renminbi for offshore counterparties. One can argue that the presence of an official clearing bank will matter only for a transitional period, because all foreign banks will have access to the onshore renminbi market once China's capital account is fully open and thus official clearing banks will then have no advantage. If, on the other hand, there is a path-dependent aspect to financial development, then official clearing bank status can have persistent effects on the geography of international finance. Hong Kong was the first offshore RMB center, and for ten years until October 2013 had the only official offshore RMB clearing bank. Since then, six additional clearing banks have been designated for Asian countries, and seven have been designated for non-Asian countries (for these purposes we classify Qatar as a non-Asian country).

The RQFII program allows designated institutional investors to invest in renminbi-denominated assets in China. Virtually all countries with official clearing banks have RQFII quotas (see Table 6). Possession of an RQFII quota encourages local fund managers to source renminbi credit for use in investing in Chinese markets. Some fund management companies have been able to access RQFII quotas in more than one jurisdiction, however, and aside from the case of Hong Kong, few if any of these quotas have been fully taken up. Both observations raise questions about whether these quotas will significantly affect the location of renminbi-denominated business. To the extent that they do, further allocation of such quotas weakens their original Asia- and specifically Hong Kong–centric bias.

Table 6. 
RMB QFII quotas
CountryQuota (RMB billions)Date Announced
Hong Kong, China 270 December 2011 
Singapore 50 October 2013 
United Kingdom 80 October 2013 
France 80 March 2014 
South Korea 80 July 2014 
Germany 80 July 2014 
Qatar 30 November 2014 
Canada 50 November 2014 
Australia 50 November 2014 
CountryQuota (RMB billions)Date Announced
Hong Kong, China 270 December 2011 
Singapore 50 October 2013 
United Kingdom 80 October 2013 
France 80 March 2014 
South Korea 80 July 2014 
Germany 80 July 2014 
Qatar 30 November 2014 
Canada 50 November 2014 
Australia 50 November 2014 

Source: Hatzvi, Nixon, and Wright (2014).

Central banks in a large set of countries in Asia and other regions—30 at the time of writing—now have swap lines with the PBOC (see Table 7). Thirteen of these bilateral swap arrangements are with Asian central banks, and eleven are with European central banks and others are with central banks in additional parts of the world. China's second largest swap line (after that with Hong Kong SAR) is with the European Central Bank, reflecting the fact that China is the European Union's second largest export market. These lines are useful for providing renminbi liquidity where official clearing banks have not been designated and for supplementing official clearing bank liquidity where they have. Access to renminbi funds can be essential in a crisis, and in the absence of such access, the local authorities will be reluctant to permit resident banks and firms to acquire renminbi exposure. In a handful of locations, notably Hong Kong, the PBOC swap line is also regularly resorted to by the local monetary authority as a mechanism for enhancing the liquidity of local renminbi markets and encouraging commercial and financial business in the currency.

Table 7. 
Swap arrangements with the People's Bank of China
CountryDateAmount in yuan
Albania 2013.09 2 billion 
Argentina 2009.03 70 billion 
Argentina 2014.07 70 billion 
Armenia 2015.03 1 billion 
Australia 2012.03 200 billion 
Australia 2015.04 200 billion 
Belarus 2009.03 20 billion 
Brazil 2013.03 190 billion 
Canada 2014.11 200 billion 
Chile 2015.05 22 billion 
European Union 2013.10 350 billion 
Hong Kong 2009.01 200 billion 
Hong Kong 2011.11 400 billion 
Hong Kong 2014.11 400 billion 
Hungary 2013.09 10 billion 
Iceland 2010.06 3.5 billion 
Iceland 2013.09 3.5 billion 
Indonesia 2009.03 100 billion 
Indonesia 2013.10 100 billion 
Kazakhstan 2011.06 7 billion 
Kazakhstan 2014.12 7 billion 
Malaysia 2009.02 80 billion 
Malaysia 2012.02 180 billion 
Mongolia 2011.05 5 billion 
Mongolia 2012.03 10 billion 
Mongolia 2014.08 15 billion 
New Zealand 2011.04 25 billion 
New Zealand 2014.05 25 billion 
Pakistan 2011.12 10 billion 
Qatar 2014.11 35 billion 
Russia 2014.10 150 billion 
Singapore 2010.07 150 billion 
Singapore 2013.03 300 billion 
South Korea 2008.12 180 billion 
South Korea 2011.10 360 billion 
South Korea 2014.10 360 billion 
Sri Lanka 2014.09 10 billion 
Suriname 2015.03 1 billion 
Switzerland 2014.07 150 billion 
Tajikistan 2015.09 0.5 billion 
Thailand 2011.12 70 billion 
Thailand 2014.12 70 billion 
Turkey 2012.02 10 billion 
Ukraine 2012.06 15 billion 
United Arab Emirates 2012.01 35 billion 
United Kingdom 2013.06 200 billion 
Uzbekistan 2011.04 0.7 billion 
CountryDateAmount in yuan
Albania 2013.09 2 billion 
Argentina 2009.03 70 billion 
Argentina 2014.07 70 billion 
Armenia 2015.03 1 billion 
Australia 2012.03 200 billion 
Australia 2015.04 200 billion 
Belarus 2009.03 20 billion 
Brazil 2013.03 190 billion 
Canada 2014.11 200 billion 
Chile 2015.05 22 billion 
European Union 2013.10 350 billion 
Hong Kong 2009.01 200 billion 
Hong Kong 2011.11 400 billion 
Hong Kong 2014.11 400 billion 
Hungary 2013.09 10 billion 
Iceland 2010.06 3.5 billion 
Iceland 2013.09 3.5 billion 
Indonesia 2009.03 100 billion 
Indonesia 2013.10 100 billion 
Kazakhstan 2011.06 7 billion 
Kazakhstan 2014.12 7 billion 
Malaysia 2009.02 80 billion 
Malaysia 2012.02 180 billion 
Mongolia 2011.05 5 billion 
Mongolia 2012.03 10 billion 
Mongolia 2014.08 15 billion 
New Zealand 2011.04 25 billion 
New Zealand 2014.05 25 billion 
Pakistan 2011.12 10 billion 
Qatar 2014.11 35 billion 
Russia 2014.10 150 billion 
Singapore 2010.07 150 billion 
Singapore 2013.03 300 billion 
South Korea 2008.12 180 billion 
South Korea 2011.10 360 billion 
South Korea 2014.10 360 billion 
Sri Lanka 2014.09 10 billion 
Suriname 2015.03 1 billion 
Switzerland 2014.07 150 billion 
Tajikistan 2015.09 0.5 billion 
Thailand 2011.12 70 billion 
Thailand 2014.12 70 billion 
Turkey 2012.02 10 billion 
Ukraine 2012.06 15 billion 
United Arab Emirates 2012.01 35 billion 
United Kingdom 2013.06 200 billion 
Uzbekistan 2011.04 0.7 billion 

Source: Garcia-Herrero and Xia (2013), AP, China Daily, PBoC, Xinhua, Reuters, Bloomberg, Reserve Bank of Australia, Reserve Bank of New Zealand.

Garcia-Herrero and Xia (2013) and Liao and McDowell (2015) have analyzed who is on the receiving end of these arrangements and why. We follow them in analyzing the determinants of their incidence, using an updated list of swap agreements for 166 countries. The dependent variable is possession of a bilateral swap arrangement with the PBOC, and explanatory variables include economic size, trade and financial integration with China, distance from China, and a variety of other macroeconomic indicators. To capture regionalization, we add a dummy variable for Asian countries. This allows us to test whether Asian countries are ceteris paribus more likely than countries in other parts of the world to receive swap lines from the PBOC.

As shown in Table 8, the dummy variable for Asian countries is uniformly indistinguishable from zero for both the probit estimation of entering a bilateral swap arrangement and the amount of swap given. Unsurprisingly, the partner's GDP is important for both decisions. Larger economies are more likely to enter into a swap arrangement with China, and such arrangements are more likely to have a larger amount. The PBOC does not appear to prefer Asian countries when extending bilateral swap arrangements, or so it would appear after controlling for other variables such as the size of the economy, financial and trade flows, and inflation. Similar to Cheung, Lin, and Zhan (2016), we show trade partnerships matter for bilateral swap arrangements as shown in Table 8A and Table 8B.

Table 8. 
Determinants of bilateral swaps
A. Determinants of bilateral swap arrangements 
 (1) (2) (3) (4) 
Ln GDP (US$, real) 0.168*** 0.211*** 0.201*** 0.197*** 
 (3.07) (3.38) (2.95) (2.80) 
Free trade agreement 0.662** 0.600* 0.608 0.391 
 (2.22) (1.96) (1.55) (0.87) 
Ln distance to Beijing −0.473** −0.497** −0.594** −0.220 
 (−2.47) (−2.49) (−2.16) (−0.53) 
Past default  0.446 0.504 0.428 
  (1.25) (1.35) (1.05) 
Open capital account  −0.136 −0.218** −0.214* 
  (−1.64) (−2.01) (−1.83) 
Rule of law   −0.280 −0.477 
   (−0.57) (−0.91) 
Corruption Index   0.450 0.548 
   (1.02) (1.20) 
Asia   −0.060 1.091 
   (−0.12) (1.28) 
Other Asia    0.909 
    (1.61) 
Europe    0.809* 
    (1.70) 
America    0.296 
    (0.53) 
N 467 467 467 467 
Pseudo R2 0.1744 0.2077 0.2213 0.2437 
B. Determinants of bilateral swap amount 
 (1) (2) (3) (4) 
Ln GDP (US$, real) 0.041 0.033 0.080 0.186 
 (0.29) (0.23) (0.51) (0.66) 
Share of exports 0.083*** 0.074*** 0.076*** 0.075*** 
 (3.54) (2.99) (3.03) (2.99) 
Distance to Beijing −0.084 −0.030 −0.264 −0.484 
 (−0.15) (−0.05) (−0.38) (−0.57) 
Free trade 1.869* 1.594 1.644 1.889 
 (1.85) (1.29) (1.33) (1.40) 
Overseas direct investment  0.095 0.095 0.099 
  (1.50) (1.49) (1.54) 
     
Past default   0.848 1.035 
   (1.00) (1.09) 
Inflation history   −0.009 −0.014 
   (−0.19) (−0.30) 
Open capital account    −0.123 
    (−0.45) 
Mills ratio −1.731** −1.726** −1.403* −0.900 
 (−2.51) (−2.51) (−1.83) (−0.66) 
adj. R2 0.1224 0.1267 0.1286 0.129 
N 467 467 467 467 
A. Determinants of bilateral swap arrangements 
 (1) (2) (3) (4) 
Ln GDP (US$, real) 0.168*** 0.211*** 0.201*** 0.197*** 
 (3.07) (3.38) (2.95) (2.80) 
Free trade agreement 0.662** 0.600* 0.608 0.391 
 (2.22) (1.96) (1.55) (0.87) 
Ln distance to Beijing −0.473** −0.497** −0.594** −0.220 
 (−2.47) (−2.49) (−2.16) (−0.53) 
Past default  0.446 0.504 0.428 
  (1.25) (1.35) (1.05) 
Open capital account  −0.136 −0.218** −0.214* 
  (−1.64) (−2.01) (−1.83) 
Rule of law   −0.280 −0.477 
   (−0.57) (−0.91) 
Corruption Index   0.450 0.548 
   (1.02) (1.20) 
Asia   −0.060 1.091 
   (−0.12) (1.28) 
Other Asia    0.909 
    (1.61) 
Europe    0.809* 
    (1.70) 
America    0.296 
    (0.53) 
N 467 467 467 467 
Pseudo R2 0.1744 0.2077 0.2213 0.2437 
B. Determinants of bilateral swap amount 
 (1) (2) (3) (4) 
Ln GDP (US$, real) 0.041 0.033 0.080 0.186 
 (0.29) (0.23) (0.51) (0.66) 
Share of exports 0.083*** 0.074*** 0.076*** 0.075*** 
 (3.54) (2.99) (3.03) (2.99) 
Distance to Beijing −0.084 −0.030 −0.264 −0.484 
 (−0.15) (−0.05) (−0.38) (−0.57) 
Free trade 1.869* 1.594 1.644 1.889 
 (1.85) (1.29) (1.33) (1.40) 
Overseas direct investment  0.095 0.095 0.099 
  (1.50) (1.49) (1.54) 
     
Past default   0.848 1.035 
   (1.00) (1.09) 
Inflation history   −0.009 −0.014 
   (−0.19) (−0.30) 
Open capital account    −0.123 
    (−0.45) 
Mills ratio −1.731** −1.726** −1.403* −0.900 
 (−2.51) (−2.51) (−1.83) (−0.66) 
adj. R2 0.1224 0.1267 0.1286 0.129 
N 467 467 467 467 

Source: GDP data are from World Bank. Distance from Beijing is from Kristian Skrede Gleditsch, accessed through http://privatewww.essex.ac.uk/∼ksg/data-5.html and calculated using Google Maps. Export data is from UN Comtrade and Observatory of Economic Complexity. Chinese overseas FDI data is from CEIC. Capital account openness uses the Chin-Ito index, accessed through http://web.pdx.edu/∼ito/Chinn-Ito_website.htm Default data collected from Moody’s. Inflation, rule of law, and corruption index are from the World Bank and IMF. Free-trade agreements are accessed online through the Ministry of Commerce, the People's Republic of China (http://fta.mofcom.gov.cn/english/index.shtml).

Note: Table 8A dependent variable is a dummy for bilateral swap arrangement that equals 1 if there is a swap arrangement between China and the specified country. Table 8B dependent variable is the natural log of the bilateral swap amount given in Table 7. Asia dummy equals 1 for East Asian and Southeast Asian countries, including Hong Kong SAR.

***Statistically significant at the 1 percent level; **statistically significant at the 5 percent level; *statistically significant at the 10 percent level.

Finally, China has supplemented these bilateral renminbi swaps with the BRICS Bank Contingent Reserve Arrangement (CRA). Through the BRICS Bank, members will lend money to one another for development projects, where some of that money will presumably be denominated in the currency of the lender. Under the CRA, participating central banks will be able to draw up to US$ 100 billion of international reserves from one another, subject to certain conditions. China has made the largest initial commitment, of US$ 41 billion, to the CRA.

Revealingly, China's partners in this arrangement include countries both within (India and Russia) and outside Asia (Brazil and South Africa). CRA capital allocations and quotas are shown in Table 9. But it is not clear whether CRA lending by China will be in dollars or renminbi (indeed, the initial BRICS CRA treaty refers to dollars). The CRA cannot therefore automatically be viewed as a mechanism for promoting use of the renminbi within the region.

Table 9. 
The BRICS contingent reserve arrangement
CountryCommitted ResourcesaAccess to CRA Resourcesb
China 41 billion USD 50 percent 
Brazil 18 billion USD 100 percent 
Russia 18 billion USD 100 percent 
India 18 billion USD 100 percent 
South Africa 5 billion USD 200 percent 
Total 100 billion USD  
CountryCommitted ResourcesaAccess to CRA Resourcesb
China 41 billion USD 50 percent 
Brazil 18 billion USD 100 percent 
Russia 18 billion USD 100 percent 
India 18 billion USD 100 percent 
South Africa 5 billion USD 200 percent 
Total 100 billion USD  

Source: BRICS Information Centre, University of Toronto (2014). See www.brics.utoronto.ca

Note: a. As of 15 July 2014.

b. Parties can access resources subject to the maximum access limits equal to the specified percentage of each party's individual commitment.

Although the renminbi is an increasingly popular global payments currency, its 2.79 percent share of global payments is dwarfed by the 45 percent share of the dollar.4 The dollar is still the preferred reserve currency, and is still far and away the dominant currency in global foreign exchange markets, as noted earlier. These facts reflect the dollar's first-mover advantage, the depth and liquidity of U.S. financial markets, the close commercial and financial ties of other countries with the U.S. economy (ties that are larger than China's at market exchange rates) and America's geopolitical and military leverage (which remains considerable, even if in decline).

The alternative is to argue that the renminbi is destined to become an important vehicle for cross-border transactions, not so much globally, but in Asia. This argument is lent plausibility by China's strong trade ties with its Asian neighbors. It is supported by the fact that China has been running persistent trade deficits with the rest of Asia, thereby enabling other Asian countries to accumulate the renminbi-denominated reserves needed to operate a renminbi-based system (Chey 2012).5 Swift data on international payments are consistent with these presumptions. Although they show that the renminbi is the vehicle for less than 3 percent of payments worldwide, it is already used in the majority of payments with China and Hong Kong.

Thus, if the renminbi is to play an international role, it is most likely to do so in Asia where it has special advantages. This can be argued on three grounds. First, China and other Asian countries are natural economic partners. Li, Li, and Ding (2004) document the existence of an exceptionally large elasticity of China's imports from other East Asian economies with respect to Chinese GDP. Given the prospect of rapid Chinese GDP growth, they conclude that China will become the largest trading economy in East Asia in the next 20 years, with about half of its imports coming from the region. According to data from the General Administration of Customs of China, China's imports from major East Asian economies (Hong Kong, Japan, South Korea, India, and ASEAN) already account for 38 percent of its total imports, and imports from Asia as a whole (including the West and Central Asian countries) represent 55 percent of its total imports (estimates for 2014).

Underlying these patterns is the fact that trade costs still matter importantly for cross-border commercial transactions, and distance is still relevant to trade costs (see, e.g., Anderson and van Wincoop 2004). Transport costs are a significant portion of total trade costs (where the latter include also costs of insurance, time in transit, and local distribution). Abe and Wilson (2009), for their part, confirm that transport costs increase with distance. More generally, these costs can be inferred from differences in the prices of the same products in different countries. Feenstra (1998) famously contrasts the cost in different markets of Mattel's Barbie doll), from the difference between the inclusive cost of insurance and freight and free on board prices, and from the predominant mode of transportation (and from the posted costs of utilizing that mode). To be sure, the association of transport costs with distance varies with the presence or absence of natural ports, long coastlines, and mountain ranges. But none of this changes the fact that Asian countries, and, in particular, those that border the South China Sea, are natural trade partners.

Another way of gauging whether economies are natural trade partners is on the basis of relative resource endowments. There is no question that resource endowments vary widely within Asia. For example, China is poorly endowed in certain natural resources compared with some of its Asian neighbors: It possesses little in the way of clean fossil fuels compared with, say, Malaysia, and is the world's largest petroleum importer. Further, its labor force peaked in 2010, and, as a result, unskilled labor is becoming increasingly scarce relative to say, Indonesia, India, and Bangladesh. It follows that China will export goods embodying skilled and semi-skilled labor and capital and import goods that make more intensive use of raw materials, energy, and unskilled labor—again making Asian countries like Indonesia, India, and Bangladesh natural trading partners. Consistent with this presumption, trade among the economies in question has been growing more rapidly than global trade, and more rapidly than China's trade overall.

Another dimension is intra-industry trade. Because of the development of international supply chains, different countries specialize in different (vertical) stages of a production process and produce different components of a final product or set of products. This has been a large component of Asian trade flows throughout the rapid economic development of Asia since the mid 1980s. China has long been involved in these regional supply chains, most prominently in the case of consumer electronics, importing semiconductors from Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan, and combining them with other components before exporting a final product. On the demand side, it is likely that Asia will become an increasingly important destination for these Chinese products, as these countries increase income and wealth per capita and develop their middle classes. Accordingly, intra-industry trade between China and other Asian countries is likely to increase further, which will provide consistent momentum for intra-industry trade and for renminbi use for cross-border transactions in the region.

One objection is that many of the supply chains in which China is involved are global, and not regional; the country imports iPhone design from Sunnyvale, California, before exporting the assembled product back to the United States. But with the articulation of supply chains, production has grown increasingly susceptible to disruption by climatic and political shocks. As these risks come to be better appreciated, producers have relocated supply chain-related production to sites closer to the point of final sale, which are less susceptible to natural and economic disruptions and where political conditions, by virtue of their proximity, are better understood. A case in point is how U.S. firms in a variety of industries have relocated the production of components from China and other Asian countries to Mexico. These observations point to the likelihood that we will continue to observe the disproportionate growth of intra-Asian trade.

An abundance of evidence suggests that distance also continues to play a role in international financial transactions. Portes, Rey, and Oh (2001) study cross-border financial transactions in U.S. equities and bonds and show that distance still matters after controlling for other determinants of the volume of these transactions. Analyzing FDI flows, Brainard (1997), Gao (2009), and Paniagua (2011) show that such flows vary inversely and significantly with distance. Di Giovanni (2002) shows that distance matters for cross-border mergers-and-acquisitions-related capital flows. The association between cross-border financial flows and proximity presumably reflects costs of information acquisition and corporate control, which historically have tended to increase with distance. To the extent that this remains the case today, the observation points to the disproportionate growth of cross-border financial transactions within Asia and a role for the dominant regional currency in those transactions.

A second basis for arguing that the renminbi is likely to be an important vehicle for cross-border transactions mainly in Asia points to Beijing's Asia-specific institutional and policy initiatives. China's Silk Road Initiative was designed to promote trade and economic integration in Central Asia. Also known as the “Belt and Road Initiative,” this was laid out by President Xi Jinping in visits to Central and Southeast Asia in 2013 and has been backed by the country's National Development and Reform Commission. The plan envisages enhanced connectivity within and among Asia, Europe, and Africa via land and adjacent sea routes, although it appears to be centered on Central and Southeast Asia. The Silk Road Economic Belt will run along the historic Silk Road trade route, which stretches from coastal China through Central Asia, and the Maritime Silk Road will connect China's south with Southeast Asia. Although focused on transport and other forms of physical infrastructure, the Silk Road Initiative is also intended to encompass trade facilitation, financial cooperation, and cultural exchange. Insofar as it achieves its goal of reducing transport costs, cultural barriers, and other obstacles, it has the potential to deepen, on the one hand, trade and financial interaction with China, and on the other hand, Southeast and Central Asian countries, thereby enhancing the attractiveness of use of the renminbi in this region.

China also participates in a number of regional initiatives together with ASEAN countries. As noted earlier, it signed an FTA with ASEAN in 2002, which came into effect in 2010. An FTA agreement with South Korea has also recently been signed. These agreements encourage additional trade flows between China and its Asian partners, have been responsible for some movement in the direction of freer trade in the region, and signal more of the same in the future.

Moving from trade to financial integration, China was a founding member of the Asian Bond Market Initiative (ABMI) established by the ASEAN+3 countries following the 1997–98 Asian financial crisis. The ABMI is intended to promote the growth and integration of regional debt security markets, and markets in local currency debt securities in particular, by sharing information on best practices and applying pressure for adoption. It was then followed by the creation by the same countries of an Asian Bond Market Forum (ABMF) of regular meetings between private-sector experts and officials with the goal of harmonizing regulation and standardizing market practices across the region, in this case with the explicit goal of promoting cross-border transactions in local-currency-denominated debt securities. Insofar as standardization includes standardization on a specific local currency, the currency in question will plausibly be that of the largest issuer: China.

Further, China is, along with Japan, the largest contributor to the Chiang Mai Initiative Multilateralization (CMIM) through which the ASEAN+3 countries have agreed to extend swap lines and credits to one another. This is a regional supplement to the global network of central bank swap lines, including the PBOC swap lines described earlier. It was established in 2000 as the Chiang Mai Initiative, a network of bilateral swaps, and reorganized in 2010, nominally as a single reserve pool, now amounting to US$ 240 billion. China (including Hong Kong) and Japan each contribute 32 percent of the collective reserve pool (for national contributions see Table 10). Most of these arrangements are specified as swaps of local currencies for U.S. dollars, but four (China–Japan, China–Philippines, China–Korea, and Japan–Korea) involve the partners’ local currencies. In addition to the practical uses of swap arrangements, the CMIM and the other China–ASEAN initiatives signal that China and ASEAN are willing to cooperate in developing a larger regional network.

Table 10. 
CMI multilateralization contributions, purchasing, and voting
Financial contribution
USD (billion)Percent (%)Purchasing multipleTotal voting power percent (%)
China (Mainland)a 68.40 28.5 0.5 25.43 
Hong Kong, China 8.40 3.5 2.5 2.98 
Japan 76.80 32 0.5 28.41 
Korea 38.40 16 14.77 
Plus 3 192 80  71.59 
Indonesia 9.104 3.793 2.5 4.369 
Thailand 9.104 3.793 2.5 4.369 
Malaysia 9.104 3.793 2.5 4.369 
Singapore 9.104 3.793 2.5 4.369 
Philippines 9.104 3.793 2.5 4.369 
Vietnam 2.00 0.833 1.847 
Cambodia 0.24 0.1 1.222 
Myanmar 0.12 0.05 1.179 
Brunei 0.06 0.025 1.158 
Lao PDR 0.06 0.025 1.158 
ASEAN 48 20  28.41 
Total 240 100  100 
Financial contribution
USD (billion)Percent (%)Purchasing multipleTotal voting power percent (%)
China (Mainland)a 68.40 28.5 0.5 25.43 
Hong Kong, China 8.40 3.5 2.5 2.98 
Japan 76.80 32 0.5 28.41 
Korea 38.40 16 14.77 
Plus 3 192 80  71.59 
Indonesia 9.104 3.793 2.5 4.369 
Thailand 9.104 3.793 2.5 4.369 
Malaysia 9.104 3.793 2.5 4.369 
Singapore 9.104 3.793 2.5 4.369 
Philippines 9.104 3.793 2.5 4.369 
Vietnam 2.00 0.833 1.847 
Cambodia 0.24 0.1 1.222 
Myanmar 0.12 0.05 1.179 
Brunei 0.06 0.025 1.158 
Lao PDR 0.06 0.025 1.158 
ASEAN 48 20  28.41 
Total 240 100  100 

Source: ASEAN+3 Macroeconomic Research Office (2015). See: www.amro-asia.org

Note: a. China, including Hong Kong, contributes US$ 76.80 billion and has 28.41% of the voting shares.

Like other swaps, the availability of local-currency lines of credit through the CMIM will encourage regulators to permit banks and firms under their jurisdiction to incur exposures in foreign currencies, since local central banks gain the power to engage in at least limited last-resort lending in those currencies. It is worth noting that the renminbi is the currency that appears most frequently in this connection (in three out of four cases). The CMIM thus provides a natural institutional platform for the renminbi in the ASEAN+3 region.

Use of the renminbi by commercial banks and enterprises in the region should in turn encourage Asian central banks to hold more renminbi in their reserve portfolios, thus enabling them to stabilize the renminbi–local currency exchange rate and act as lender of last resort in renminbi to the banks and firms in question. In fact, the majority of ASEAN+3 central banks already have indicated that they have added the renminbi to their reserve portfolios. Early adopters include Malaysia, Cambodia, the Philippines, Singapore, and Thailand (for the complete list see Table 11).

Table 11. 
RMB as official reserve by country
CountryDateaAmountType
Norway October 2006 up to $1.5 bn onshore 
Malaysia September 2010 undisclosed sovereign 
Hong Kong October 2010 5−10% ($16−$31 bn) sovereign 
Belarus November 2010 undisclosed onshore 
Venezuela August 2011 undisclosed undisclosed 
Kenya August 2011 undisclosed undisclosed 
Chile September 2011 2.3% ($945 mn) undisclosed 
Nigeria September 2011 2−7% ($2.3--$4.6 bn) offshore 
Cambodia October 2011 undisclosed undisclosed 
Philippines October 2011 undisclosed undisclosed 
Russia October 2011 undisclosed undisclosed 
Singapore October 2011 up to $1 bn onshore 
Thailand November 2011 0.5% ($836 mn) off & onshore 
Austria November 2011 undisclosed onshore 
Japan December 2011 $10.3 bn sovereign 
Uruguay 2012a $0.21 bn offshore 
Macao March 2012 15.5% ($2.5 bn) off &onshore 
Bolivia May 2012 0.4% ($58 mn) offshore 
Indonesia July 2012 undisclosed onshore 
Korea July 2012 $3.3 bn onshore 
Saudi Arabia July 2012 undisclosed undisclosed 
Tanzania August 2012 undisclosed offshore 
Pakistan October 2012 undisclosed onshore 
Angola April 2013 undisclosed offshore 
Australia April 2013 $1.6 bn sovereign 
Nepal June 2013 undisclosed onshore 
South Africa June 2013 $1.5 bn off & onshore 
Taiwan October 2013 undisclosed undisclosed 
Lithuania November 2013 up to $100 mn onshore 
Namibia December 2013 undisclosed offshore 
Ghana April 2014 undisclosed undisclosed 
France April 2014 undisclosed sovereign 
Switzerland July 2014 up to $2.5 bn onshore 
Sri Lanka September 2014 undisclosed onshore 
Argentina September 2014 $1.3 bn undisclosed 
United Kingdom October 2014 $490 mn offshore 
Zimbabwe October 2014 undisclosed undisclosed 
Hungary May 2015 undisclosed undisclosed 
CountryDateaAmountType
Norway October 2006 up to $1.5 bn onshore 
Malaysia September 2010 undisclosed sovereign 
Hong Kong October 2010 5−10% ($16−$31 bn) sovereign 
Belarus November 2010 undisclosed onshore 
Venezuela August 2011 undisclosed undisclosed 
Kenya August 2011 undisclosed undisclosed 
Chile September 2011 2.3% ($945 mn) undisclosed 
Nigeria September 2011 2−7% ($2.3--$4.6 bn) offshore 
Cambodia October 2011 undisclosed undisclosed 
Philippines October 2011 undisclosed undisclosed 
Russia October 2011 undisclosed undisclosed 
Singapore October 2011 up to $1 bn onshore 
Thailand November 2011 0.5% ($836 mn) off & onshore 
Austria November 2011 undisclosed onshore 
Japan December 2011 $10.3 bn sovereign 
Uruguay 2012a $0.21 bn offshore 
Macao March 2012 15.5% ($2.5 bn) off &onshore 
Bolivia May 2012 0.4% ($58 mn) offshore 
Indonesia July 2012 undisclosed onshore 
Korea July 2012 $3.3 bn onshore 
Saudi Arabia July 2012 undisclosed undisclosed 
Tanzania August 2012 undisclosed offshore 
Pakistan October 2012 undisclosed onshore 
Angola April 2013 undisclosed offshore 
Australia April 2013 $1.6 bn sovereign 
Nepal June 2013 undisclosed onshore 
South Africa June 2013 $1.5 bn off & onshore 
Taiwan October 2013 undisclosed undisclosed 
Lithuania November 2013 up to $100 mn onshore 
Namibia December 2013 undisclosed offshore 
Ghana April 2014 undisclosed undisclosed 
France April 2014 undisclosed sovereign 
Switzerland July 2014 up to $2.5 bn onshore 
Sri Lanka September 2014 undisclosed onshore 
Argentina September 2014 $1.3 bn undisclosed 
United Kingdom October 2014 $490 mn offshore 
Zimbabwe October 2014 undisclosed undisclosed 
Hungary May 2015 undisclosed undisclosed 

Source: Liao and McDowell (2015) , Xinhua News.

Note: a. Missing month for Uruguay.

A further basis for arguing that the renminbi's future is as an international currency in Asia builds on the same observations as in Section 3 but applies to it a different spin. The vast majority of exchange rates in whose determination the renminbi now has the greatest weight are Asian currencies. The countries with the largest RQFII quotas (Hong Kong, Singapore, and Taiwan) are Asian countries. The Shanghai-Hong Kong Stock Connect, which removes barriers between equity markets in Shanghai and offshore, specifically removes those barriers between Shanghai and a principal Asian market. Moreover, the first seven countries with direct trading of their local currencies against the renminbi (Laos, Kazakhstan, Vietnam, Korea, Thailand, Japan, and Australia) were all Asian countries, as were the first countries to add the renminbi to their reserve portfolios (Hong Kong and Malaysia).

Finally, insofar as political power and leverage matter for international currency use, it is worth noting that China is best able to project such power and influence in the South China Sea and elsewhere in Asia. In terms of economic influence, there is no doubt that China plays a large role for Asian countries like Thailand, Malaysia, and Vietnam, as China is one of their most important trade and financial partners. Consistent with this, Asian countries’ willingness to participate in institutional arrangements with China reflects the fact that the same countries, too, benefit from these relationships. All these are reasons for believing that the renminbi's future is as a leading regional, not global, currency.

Forecasting is difficult. Any forecast about whether the renminbi's future is as a global or regional currency should therefore be taken with a grain of salt. Instead of forecasting, therefore, we have done our best in this paper to make the cases for both scenarios. Neither theory nor history points unambiguously in either direction, and modern evidence can be marshaled in support of either view. On the one hand, China has increasingly important economic, financial, and political links with countries not only in Asia, but throughout the world, just as China invests globally, not just in Asia. Many of China's policy initiatives, such as its bilateral free trade agreements, designating Chinese banks as official renminbi clearing banks for foreign financial centers, and concluding renminbi swap arrangements with foreign central banks, extend also to countries in Europe and the Western Hemisphere. These observations suggest that as Chinese financial markets gain depth and liquidity, the renminbi will assume a role not merely as a currency used in settling trade-related transactions, where it already functions, but also as an investment and reserve currency, not just in Asia but globally.

At the same time, however, some of China's most natural economic, financial, and political links are with neighboring Asian countries. Transport costs are still important for international trade, and they are lowest over short distances. Distance also matters for international financial transactions, whether because local knowledge dissipates with distance or because certain financial transactions are more costly across multiple time zones. These facts make China and other Asian countries logical commercial and financial partners. Asian countries that see themselves as sharing common characteristics, and specifically common economic and financial vulnerabilities, have responded with regional initiatives like the ABMI, Asian Bond Forum, Asian Bond Fund, CMIM, and ASEAN–China FTA, all of which work to further deepen economic and financial integration in the region. This suggests that the renminbi, as the currency of the largest Asian economy and leading trader, has a natural habitat in the region, and that its future is as the leading Asian currency.

As for which scenario is more likely, one can only echo Zhoa Enlai (speaking not of the French Revolution but of the French student demonstrations of 1968, in actual fact), that it is too early to tell. This paper at least identifies some of the principal factors on which the answer will hinge.

Abe
,
Kazutomo
, and
John
Wilson
.
2009
.
Weathering the Storm: Investing in Port Infrastructure to Lower Transport Costs in East Asia
.
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 4911
.
Washington, DC
:
World Bank
.
Anderson
,
James
, and
Eric van
Wincoop
.
2004
.
Trade Costs
.
Journal of Economic Literature
42
(
3
):
691
751
.
ASEAN+3 Macroeconomic Research Office
.
2015
.
Contributions, Purchasing Multiple, Maximum Swap Amount
. Available at www.amro-asia.org/the-relationship-between-amro-and-cmim/CMIM%20Contributions.
Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank
.
2016
.
Prospective Founding Members
. Available at http://euweb.aiib.org/html/aboutus/introduction/Membership/?show=0.
Bergsten
,
Fred
.
1975
.
The Dilemmas of the Dollar.
New York
:
New York University Press
.
Brainard
,
S. Lael
.
1997
.
An Empirical Assessment of the Proximity-Concentration Trade-off Between Multinational Sales and Trade
.
American Economic Review
87
(
4
):
520
544
.
BRICS Information Centre, University of Toronto
.
2014
.
Treaty for the Establishment of a BRICS Contingent Reserve Arrangement
. Available at www.brics.utoronto.ca/docs/140715-treaty.html.
Cheung
,
Yin-Wong
,
Zhitao
Lin
, and
Wenjie
Zhan
.
2016
.
China's Bilateral Currency Swap Lines
.
Global Research Unit Working Paper No. 2016–013. City University of Hong Kong
.
Chey
,
Hyoung-kyu
.
2012
.
Can the Renminbi Rise as a Global Currency? The Political Economy of Currency Internationalization
.
GRIPS Discussion Paper No. 11–20
.
Tokyo
:
National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies
.
China, Ministry of Commerce
.
2015
.
China FTA Network
. Available at http://fta.mofcom.gov.cn/english/index.shtml.
Choi
,
Nakgyoon
.
2015
.
Global Value Chains and East Asian Trade in Value-Added
.
Asian Economic Papers
14
(
3
):
129
144
.
Di Giovanni
,
Julian
.
2002
.
What Drives Capital Flows? The Case of Cross-Border M&A Activity and Financial Deepening
.
CIDER Working Paper No. C02–122
.
Berkeley
:
Center for International and Development Economic Research, University of California, Berkeley
.
Eichengreen
,
Barry
.
2014
.
International Currencies Past, Present and Future: Two Views from Economic History
.
Working Paper No. 2014–31
.
Seoul
:
Bank of Korea
.
Eichengreen
,
Barry
, and
Marc
Flandreau
.
1996
.
Blocs, Zones and Bands: International Monetary History in Light of Recent Theoretical Developments
.
Scottish Journal of Economics
43
(
4
):
398
418
.
Eichengreen
,
Barry
, and
Marc
Flandreau
.
2009
.
The Rise and Fall of the Dollar (or When Did the Dollar Replace Sterling as the Leading International Currency?)
.
European Review of Economic History
13
(
3
):
377
411
.
Farrell
,
Joseph
, and
Paul
Klemperer
.
2007
.
Coordination and Lock-In: Competition with Switching Costs and Network Effects
. In:
Handbook of Industrial Organization
, volume
3
, edited by
Mark
Armstrong
and
Robert
Porter
, pp.
1967
2072
.
Amsterdam
:
North-Holland
.
Feenstra
,
Robert
.
1998
.
Integration of Trade and Disintegration of Production in the Global Economy
.
Journal of Economic Perspectives
12
(
4
):
31
50
.
Gao
,
Shen
.
2009
.
The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on Foreign Direct Investment
.
Unpublished paper, Uppsala University
.
Garcia-Herrero
,
Alicia
, and
Le
Xia
.
2013
.
China's RMB Bilateral Swap Agreements: What Explains the Choice of Countries? Institute for Economies in Transition Discussion Paper No. 12/2013
.
Helsinki
:
Bank of Finland
.
Goldberg
,
Linda
, and
Cedric
Tille
.
2005
.
Vehicle Currency Use in International Trade
.
Staff Report No. 200
.
New York
:
Federal Reserve Bank of New York
.
Hatzvi
,
Eden
,
William
Nixon
, and
Michelle
Wright
.
2014
.
The Offshore Renminbi Market and Australia
.
RBA Bulletin
53
62
.
Helleiner
,
Eric
, and
Jonathan
Kirshner
editors.
2014
.
The Great Wall of Money: Power and Politics in China's International Monetary Relations
.
Ithaca, NY
:
Cornell University Press
.
Krugman
,
Paul
.
1980
.
Vehicle Currencies and the Structure of International Exchange
.
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking
12
(
3
):
513
526
.
Krugman
,
Paul
.
1984
.
The International Role of the Dollar: Theory and Prospect
. In:
Exchange Rate Theory and Practice
, edited by
John
Bilson
and
Richard
Marston
, pp.
261
278
.
Chicago, IL
:
University of Chicago Press
.
Li
,
Xiao
,
Junjiu
Li
, and
Yibing
Ding
.
2004
.
On the “Asianization” of Renminbi
.
The Journal of World Economy
2004
2
.
Liao
,
Steven
, and
Daniel
McDowell
.
2015
.
Redback Rising: China's Bilateral Swap Agreements and Renminbi Internationalization
.
International Studies Quarterly
59
(
3
):
401
422
.
Lindert
,
Peter
.
1969
.
Key Currencies and Gold, 1900–1913. Princeton Studies in International Finance No. 24
.
Princeton, NJ
:
International Finance Section, Princeton University, Department of Economics
.
Matsuyama
,
Kiminori
,
Nobuhiro
Kiyotaki
, and
Akihiko
Matsui
.
1993
.
Toward a Theory of International Currency
.
Review of Economic Studies
60
(
2
):
283
307
.
McKinnon
,
Ronald
.
1979
.
Money in International Exchange: The Convertible Currency System.
New York
:
Oxford University Press
.
Paniagua
,
Jordi
.
2011
.
FDI Gravity Equation: Models, Estimations and Zeros. Unpublished paper
.
Valencia, Spain
:
Catholic University of Valencia
.
Portes
,
Richard
,
Helene
Rey
, and
Yonghyup
Oh
.
2001
.
Information and Capital Flows: The Determinants of Transactions in Financial Assets
.
European Economic Review
45
(
4
):
783
796
.
Prasad
,
Eswar
.
2014
.
The Dollar Trap: How the US Dollar Tightened its Grip on Global Finance.
Princeton, NJ
:
Princeton University Press
.
Subramanian
,
Arvind
, and
Martin
Kessler
.
2013
.
The Renminbi Bloc Is Here: Asia Down and the Rest of the World to Go. Working Paper No. WP 12–19
.
Washington, DC
:
Peterson Institute of International Economics
.
Weir
,
Geoffrey
.
2015
.
Offshore RMB Centres: Some Observations of Relevance to Sydney
.
Unpublished paper
.
Whalley
,
John
, and
Chunding
Li
.
2014
.
China's Regional and Bilateral Trade Agreements
.
Voxeu.org, March
.
*

The authors acknowledge CIGI for supporting this project and Coby Hu for excellent research assistance.

1 

“The death of distance has been exaggerated,” as Anderson and van Wincoop (2004) put it in their survey of the literature on trade costs.

2 

It is possible to think that the observed correlation of other Asian currencies with the renminbi reflects the fact that they have a common correlation with the dollar. But we are controlling separately—and directly—in these regressions for their correlation with the dollar.

3 

This is in contrast to the euro, whose effect is limited to other European countries, and the dollar, which according to this methodology, is the most important exchange rate for countries in a variety of different regions, as befits a global currency.

4 

Figures are based on Swift data as released on 6 October 2015.

5 

China's trade structure is characterized by a trade surplus with developed countries in North America and Europe and a trade deficit with economies in East Asia. This can, in turn, facilitate renminbi-based exports in the emerging East Asian economies.

This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. For a full description of the license, please visit https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/legalcode.