As the number of older people in need of long-term care increases, efforts to support older people remaining in their home are intensified in most OECD countries. In this context, there is a movement towards allowing more individual choice for older people receiving publicly funded long-term care at home. Having more flexibility in terms of how to receive care can increase the older person's self-determination and that of his/her informal caregivers. Having a choice among alternative care providers can empower older people as consumers and may help strengthen the role of households in the care-management process. The main aims of this article are (i) to categorise and analyse different types of arrangements allowing home care users more choice and map the prevalence of such arrangements in OECD countries, (ii) to give an overview of some country-specific outcomes in terms of care quality for care recipients, and (iii) to discuss some implications for employment and fiscal sustainability.

As the number of older people in need of long-term care increases in OECD countries, home care continues to be the predominant – and preferred – care setting for the vast majority of households. To achieve the goal of ageing in place, a complex mix of services of acute health care, rehabilitation, long-term care, and social services is often needed, and – above a certain level of dependency – the support of a main informal carer usually becomes indispensable. Over the last 10 years, care systems in many countries have made considerable progress in moving away from the restricted choice of either receiving largely unsupported care at home from a relative or receiving formal services in a nursing home.

Against this background, the main aims of this article are (i) to categorise and analyse different types of arrangements allowing home care users more choice and map the prevalence of such arrangements in OECD countries, (ii) to give an overview of some country-specific outcomes in terms of flexibility, care quality, satisfaction and conditions for caregivers, and (iii) to discuss some of the implications for employment and fiscal sustainability.

A complete analysis of choice and flexibility in long-term care would include the provision of care both in long-term care institutions and at home and arrangements facilitating choice among alternative agencies providing formal care as well as consumer-directed employment of a personal care assistant and support of informal care. In this article, only care provided to people living at home is covered and the emphasis is put on consumer-directed employment of a personal care assistant and the support of informal community-based care.

This article covers 12 countries, namely Australia, Austria, Canada, Germany, Ireland, Japan, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, United Kingdom and the United States. This is a subset of the countries covered in the wider OECD long-term care report (OECD 2005) and includes those countries that have experience with arrangements allowing users more choice and flexibility with regard to the way care is provided, and for which sufficient information was available.

The different ways in which countries seek to increase flexibility and choice in long-term care depend, among other things, on the weight they put on formal care provision versus informal care. This, in turn, partly reflects cultural factors, and arrangements for care can be seen to represent different family models (Millar and Warman 1995; Rostgaard 2004). In general, countries with above-average public funding for long-term care tend to rely more on formal care than others, perhaps because this is found in countries with a social-democratic welfare model, where emphasis is on public provision, but this is not the full story. As illustrated by the stylised picture of long-term care systems in Figure 1, panel A, countries can broadly be subdivided into five groups:

  • In Korea, Spain and other Southern European countries long-term care is, to a large extent, provided informally within families, so that although nursing homes and other residential care institutions are predominantly funded publicly, overall long-term care provision is based on private resources to a greater extent than in other OECD countries.2

  • Austria, Luxembourg, Germany, Ireland, the United Kingdom and Australia have considerable levels of public funding for long-term care compared with countries such as Korea and Spain. A significant share of this is in the form of payments in support of informal home care either by granting these allowances directly to care recipients, allowing them to choose whether to share them with a carer informally or to purchase other forms of care (Austria, Germany and Luxembourg), or by granting long-term care allowances to relatives providing care to older people (Australia, Ireland, the United Kingdom).

  • In Japan, informal care within families plays a large role as well, but it is not supported financially by public programmes. Mandatory long-term care insurance now provides for substantial formal services as care alternatives.

  • In the United States and Canada, informal care plays some role, but is not supported much financially by public programmes. However, the increasing orientation towards consumer direction in care has brought arrangements where in some cases relatives can be employed.

  • The Netherlands, Norway and Sweden have considerable levels of public funding, but channel most of this through provision of formal services for both home care and institutional care.

Countries may increase flexibility by introducing choice either via support for informal care and/or via choice among providers of formal care. As illustrated by Figure 1, panel B, the one does not necessitate the other, and often reflects the path dependency of the particular social policy regime of the country. For instance, in Sweden, where the scope of choice for people receiving formal care is typically limited and where payments for informal care play a limited role, the introduction of choice by some local authorities currently implies moving horizontally (to the right) in the chart towards choice among a limited set of approved providers. For a country such as Sweden, this move towards more market provision represents some divergence from the traditional Nordic model of basically a publicly provided care system. Germany, with a much more recent public involvement in the organisation of provision and financing of care for the elderly, did not have the same public tradition to consider. Here, the development of the care system placed Germany vertically (upwards) in this chart with the introduction of the Cash Allowance for Care (Pflegegeld), and also horizontally (to the right) as the long-term care insurance reform in 1995 implied more choice among formal care providers. An important point is that improving flexibility of care via choice does not necessarily imply privatisation of funding. Whether countries maintain (or expand) public funding or coverage of long-term care costs can be a separate issue from whether they channel it through formal long-term care services.

Figure 1. 

Stylised picture of long-term care provision in OECD countries.

Figure 1. 

Stylised picture of long-term care provision in OECD countries.

Close modal

With respect to choice among agencies providing home care or among institutions, there are very fundamental differences between countries. On the one side, the Nordic countries have build up provision of formal home care services almost exclusively via public agencies, and therefore introducing choice among alternative public and private providers comes in as an ‘additional’ element which has been a matter of policy debates over the last decade or so. On the other side, the long-term care systems in most other countries are ‘born’ with more choice among providers when older people get publicly funded formal care services. The United States has considerable levels of public funding for long-term care but it is targeted at people with low income, and the supply of care services and the market for nursing homes and other providers of home care and assisted living are therefore in part shaped by the demand from older people paying privately. Older people receiving care supported by Medicaid therefore often have a choice among different agencies. In countries such as Germany, where public funding for long-term care (as for health care) is based on social insurance funds, the purchaser–provider split (which is talked about as a policy innovation in Nordic countries) is given from the outset. This construction more easily facilitates choice among providers of formal care services as there is not one incumbent agency. That the systems are very different with respect to the extent to which they involve public or private providers of formal care services can be exemplified by the situation for institutional care (see Figure 2).

Figure 2. 

Public and private long-term care institutions for older people. Based on the number of residents, late 1990s. Source: OECD, based on sources collected prior to the Health Project.

Figure 2. 

Public and private long-term care institutions for older people. Based on the number of residents, late 1990s. Source: OECD, based on sources collected prior to the Health Project.

Close modal

A number of fairly different arrangements are used in OECD countries to allow more choice for people receiving long-term care at home. Although they differ in many respects they can usefully be subdivided into three main groups, as shown in Table 1, panels A, B and C.3

TABLE 1. 
Personal budgets, consumer directed employment of care assistants and payments for informal care for older persons Information refering to most recent year available, often 2004 for rules and payment levels, but typically 2002 or 2003 for the number of users
Monthly payment levelsAll public home care 2
CountryProgrammeDescriptionCan relatives be employed or supported?LowestMain or averageHighestShare of 65+ population receiving home care via this programmeShare of 65+ pop.Spending per user
% of private consumption per capita 1 Monthly amount in nat. currency and USD PPP%%% of private cons. pc.
A. Personal budgets and consumer directed employment of care assistants3 
          
Netherlands Personal Budget for Care and Nursing Persoons- gebonden budgets Personal budgets can purchasw agency care, directly employ a care assistant and also pay some cash for appliances and informal care Yes, 4 but not if living together The size of each budget is equal to what would have been the public expenditure on formal services net of user charges less an “efficiency deduction” of 15–20%. 0.85 12.3 57% 
Norway Care Wage Omsorgslønn Pays relatives or others for caring when this is considered better than agency care. Typically 3–10 hrs/week. Yes The carer is paid for a given number of hours typically using the hourly wage of a care assistant in the public agency. 0.3 18.0 57% 
Sweden Carer's Salary Anstälda anhørige The person giving care is treated as employed by the public agency. Scheme used in remote areas. Yes, but nit if older than 65years. Person giving care is paid a salary similar to care assistants in the public agency and has similar social security protection. 0.1 9.1 101% 
United Kingdom Direct Payments New scheme. Older persons eligible for care can now choose a direct payment for purchase of care. Yes, 6 but not if living together Same as the net costs of the services assessed as required. 0.047 20.3 13% 
United States Consumer Directed home care Consumers can hire and supervise a personal care assistant who will be paid by Medicaid for a specific number of hours. Most prg. allow relatives but not spouses Payment levels vary across prg.s reaching up to $2760 a month in Kansas' HCBSFE prg. and up to 66 hrs/week in California's IHSS prg. 0.5   
United States8 Cash & Counseling Demonstration and Evaluation prg. in Arkansas, Florida and New Jersey. Budget can pay also for home adaptation etc. Yes 20% $400 36% $723 69% $1400 Experimental with 1000–2000 older persons in each state 2.8 60% 
B. Payments to the person needing care who can spend it as she/he likes, but has to acquire sufficient care9 
Austria10 11 Cash Allowance for Care Pflegegeld All public support for home care is through this allowance. Recipients can purchase formal care if they wish. Yes 13% €145; $154 35% €405; $430 132% €1532; $1626 14.8 14.8 na. 
Germany10 Cash Allowance for Care Pflegegeld Under the long-term care insurance, recipients can choose between care in-kind and this allowance. Yes 18% €205; $209 27% €311; $317 57% €665; $678 5.712 7.1 53% 
Luxembourg Cash Allowance for care Prest. en espèces Under the long-term care insurance, recipients can choose to replace the first 7 hrs/week of care in-kind by this allowance. Yes 15% €267; $272 39% €679; $693 63% €1100; $1122 3.913 4.3 32% 
Sweden Attendance Allowance Anhørig bidrag Cash payment to the person needing care who can then pay informal caregivers. Minimum care need of 17 hrs/week. Yes 52% Sek5000; $515 0.1 9.1 101% 
United Kingdom14 Attendance Allowance A cash benefit to persons aged 65+ who have been needing care at home for at least six months. Yes 16%£170; $266  24% £255; $399 19.3 20.3 13% 
C. Income support payments to informal caregivers15 
Australia16 Carer Payment For people who cannot support themselves because caring. Yes Yes 53% A$934; $682 0.9 14.7 28% 
Australia 16 Carer's Allowance For people who live with and care for somebody at home. No Yes 11% A$191; $139 4.0   
Canada Compassionate Care Benefit A short-term benefit for persons caring for somebody with a terminal condition. No17 Yes Pays 55% of normal employment income. New scheme Max payment is C$1790; $1467 per month. New scheme introduced in 2004 na. na. 
Ireland18 Carer Allowance For carers with low income who live with and look after people needing full-time care. Yes Yes Nil  50% €683; $683    
Ireland19 Carer's Benefit A payment to insured persons leaving work temporarily for someone needing full-time care. No Yes  47% €649; $649  Scheme introduced in 2000 ca. 5 61% 
Japan Allowance for Families Caring for Elderly Only if low-income family, heavy care needs and not supported from long-term care insurance. Yes Yes  5% ¥8333; $60  New scheme playing a limited role 5.5 39% 
Sweden Care Leave Statutory right to take leave from work for up to 60 days when caring for a terminally ill relative. No Must be a relative or close friend Pays 80% of normal employment income  9.1 101% 
United Kingdom Carer's Allowance For low-income persons caring 35+ hrs/week for someone receiving Attend. Allowance.20 Yes Yes 18% £192; $300  20.3 13% 
Monthly payment levelsAll public home care 2
CountryProgrammeDescriptionCan relatives be employed or supported?LowestMain or averageHighestShare of 65+ population receiving home care via this programmeShare of 65+ pop.Spending per user
% of private consumption per capita 1 Monthly amount in nat. currency and USD PPP%%% of private cons. pc.
A. Personal budgets and consumer directed employment of care assistants3 
          
Netherlands Personal Budget for Care and Nursing Persoons- gebonden budgets Personal budgets can purchasw agency care, directly employ a care assistant and also pay some cash for appliances and informal care Yes, 4 but not if living together The size of each budget is equal to what would have been the public expenditure on formal services net of user charges less an “efficiency deduction” of 15–20%. 0.85 12.3 57% 
Norway Care Wage Omsorgslønn Pays relatives or others for caring when this is considered better than agency care. Typically 3–10 hrs/week. Yes The carer is paid for a given number of hours typically using the hourly wage of a care assistant in the public agency. 0.3 18.0 57% 
Sweden Carer's Salary Anstälda anhørige The person giving care is treated as employed by the public agency. Scheme used in remote areas. Yes, but nit if older than 65years. Person giving care is paid a salary similar to care assistants in the public agency and has similar social security protection. 0.1 9.1 101% 
United Kingdom Direct Payments New scheme. Older persons eligible for care can now choose a direct payment for purchase of care. Yes, 6 but not if living together Same as the net costs of the services assessed as required. 0.047 20.3 13% 
United States Consumer Directed home care Consumers can hire and supervise a personal care assistant who will be paid by Medicaid for a specific number of hours. Most prg. allow relatives but not spouses Payment levels vary across prg.s reaching up to $2760 a month in Kansas' HCBSFE prg. and up to 66 hrs/week in California's IHSS prg. 0.5   
United States8 Cash & Counseling Demonstration and Evaluation prg. in Arkansas, Florida and New Jersey. Budget can pay also for home adaptation etc. Yes 20% $400 36% $723 69% $1400 Experimental with 1000–2000 older persons in each state 2.8 60% 
B. Payments to the person needing care who can spend it as she/he likes, but has to acquire sufficient care9 
Austria10 11 Cash Allowance for Care Pflegegeld All public support for home care is through this allowance. Recipients can purchase formal care if they wish. Yes 13% €145; $154 35% €405; $430 132% €1532; $1626 14.8 14.8 na. 
Germany10 Cash Allowance for Care Pflegegeld Under the long-term care insurance, recipients can choose between care in-kind and this allowance. Yes 18% €205; $209 27% €311; $317 57% €665; $678 5.712 7.1 53% 
Luxembourg Cash Allowance for care Prest. en espèces Under the long-term care insurance, recipients can choose to replace the first 7 hrs/week of care in-kind by this allowance. Yes 15% €267; $272 39% €679; $693 63% €1100; $1122 3.913 4.3 32% 
Sweden Attendance Allowance Anhørig bidrag Cash payment to the person needing care who can then pay informal caregivers. Minimum care need of 17 hrs/week. Yes 52% Sek5000; $515 0.1 9.1 101% 
United Kingdom14 Attendance Allowance A cash benefit to persons aged 65+ who have been needing care at home for at least six months. Yes 16%£170; $266  24% £255; $399 19.3 20.3 13% 
C. Income support payments to informal caregivers15 
Australia16 Carer Payment For people who cannot support themselves because caring. Yes Yes 53% A$934; $682 0.9 14.7 28% 
Australia 16 Carer's Allowance For people who live with and care for somebody at home. No Yes 11% A$191; $139 4.0   
Canada Compassionate Care Benefit A short-term benefit for persons caring for somebody with a terminal condition. No17 Yes Pays 55% of normal employment income. New scheme Max payment is C$1790; $1467 per month. New scheme introduced in 2004 na. na. 
Ireland18 Carer Allowance For carers with low income who live with and look after people needing full-time care. Yes Yes Nil  50% €683; $683    
Ireland19 Carer's Benefit A payment to insured persons leaving work temporarily for someone needing full-time care. No Yes  47% €649; $649  Scheme introduced in 2000 ca. 5 61% 
Japan Allowance for Families Caring for Elderly Only if low-income family, heavy care needs and not supported from long-term care insurance. Yes Yes  5% ¥8333; $60  New scheme playing a limited role 5.5 39% 
Sweden Care Leave Statutory right to take leave from work for up to 60 days when caring for a terminally ill relative. No Must be a relative or close friend Pays 80% of normal employment income  9.1 101% 
United Kingdom Carer's Allowance For low-income persons caring 35+ hrs/week for someone receiving Attend. Allowance.20 Yes Yes 18% £192; $300  20.3 13% 

1. Percentages of private consumption are calculated based on household final consumption expenditure per capita in the accounts statistics which is roughly equal to average disposable househould income per capita. Payment levels in USD at purchasing power parity (PPP) are calculated using 2003 exchange rates. For comparability across programmes, all payment levels are shown as monthly amounts even if some programmes determine the payment each person in eligible for on a weekly basis.

2. The total share of the population aged 65 and over receiving home care funded by some public programme or mandatory insurance (including the schemes shown in this table) and the average public spending per person receiving home is shown here for comparison. See Huber (2005) for details on the compilation of the underlying data.

3. The person receiving care does not pay income tax of the benefits from these schemes, but as there is a formal employment relationship, the caregiver will be taxed of the income she/he receives.

4. If the person needing care lives together with healthy adult relatives then they are obliged to do the necessary housekeeping tasks irrespective of whether they are in working age or have retired. Relatives living in the same household can therefore only be employed to provide care beyond these functions. In practice, employment of relatives living in the same household is seen mostly for adult disabled and only rarely for care.

5. Personal Budgets were introduced in 1995 and grew to a total of 23,000 users in year 2000 and 54,000 in 2003. In 2003, about a third of all users were older persons which corresponds to 0.8% of the population aged 65+ as shown in the table.

6. With an adjustment of legislation from April 2002, people can use their direct payment to pay a relative who lives with them, but only in exceptional circumstances where they and their local council consider that this is the only satisfactory way of meeting their care needs.

7. Since introduced in 2000 for older persons also, the number of users in England aged 65 and over has grown from only 500 in year 2000/1 to 2,700 in 2002/3 corresponding to 0.04% of the population aged 65+.

8. The average monthly payment levels differ in the three states involved, from $400 in Arkansas, and $723 in Florida to $1400 in New Jersey.

9. The person receiving care does not pay income tax of these benefits. Nor does an informal caregiver living together with the person, as the payment is simply shared within the household. Presumably, informal caregivers from outside the household rarely report money they receive in this way as income when filing their tax statement, and the person receiving care has no obligation to report to whom they pass on money.

10. The middle-column “Main or average” shows a weighted average of payment levels received by beneficiaries aged 65+. “Lowest” and “Highest” show bottom and top of payment scale.

11. Because this cash allowance is also the channel for support to persons with very intensive care needs requiring institutional care, the highest level reaches 132% of average private consumption per capita. But only 1.2% of older persons receiving support are at this highest level. The lowest payment level is available for persons needing care for 12 hours or more per week.

12. This includes those choosing to have all the support they are eligible for as a cash allowance (4.7% of the 65+ population) as well as those choosing a combination of cash and services (1.0% of the 65+ population). In addition to this, 0.8% of the 65+ population receive support from the long-term care insurance while choosing to have all as services. This calculation assumes an equal propensity to choose the three options for the three quarters of long-term care insurance recipients aged 65 years or over and the one quarter younger than 65. Data for 2001.

13. This includes those choosing to have all the support they are eligible for as a cash allowance (2.1% of the 65+ population) as well as those choosing a combination of cash and services (1.8% of the 65+ population). In addition to this, 0.4% of the 65+ population receive support from the long-term care insurance while choosing to have all as services. This calculation assume an equal propensity to choose the three options for the two thirds of long-term care insurance recipients aged 65 or over and the one third younger than 65 years. Data for the number of beneficiaries on 30 June 2003.

14. Depending on individual circumstances such as whether care is needed also at night, the payment levels vary more than indicated by the typical low- and high-level payments shown in the table.

15. These income support payments are typically taxed as income for the caregiver (but not for all schemes), and the net-of-tax amount will therefore be smaller than the gross amount shown in the table. How important this difference is depends also on what other income the caregiver has since with progressive tax scales, the net-of-tax amount will be smallest for high-income caregivers. As many of the schemes are targeted at low-income caregivers, however, the actual difference between gross and net amounts may be limited.

16. Data for the number of recipients refer to June 2002 while payment levels are those that came into force by January 1, 2003. The Carer Payment will under most circumstances be liable for taxation when caring for an older person. Carer Allowance is newer taxed as income. If Carer Payment is received by both in a couple, the monthly payment level is A$780 per recipient (45% of private consumption pc).

17. As the level of payments is a percentage of normal employment income, it will grow with income in the interval below the ceiling. But for persons with low income and children there is a Family Supplement.

18. The maximum amount shown in the table applies for a person aged 66 or over and with very little income giving care to one person. If caring for more than one person, the maximum is €1026 per month. For caregivers aged under 66 years the allowance is reduced by €79–118, while for each dependent child it is raised by €36–73 per month.

19. Amount applies if caring for one person. If caring for more than one, the benefit is €973 per month, and for each dependent child the caregiver has, the benefit is raised by €36–73 per month.

20. In 2002, the Carer's Allowance has been made available also for care-givers aged 65 and over. The payment is only available for persons with disposable income below £342 a month (32% of private consumption pc.) where disposable income is calculated net of spending on respite care etc. The benefit is taxable.

Source: OECD based on replies to the long-term care questionnaire and research into various other national sources.

3.1 (A) Personal budgets and consumer-directed employment of care assistants

As an alternative to provision of formal home care via a single designated agency, different arrangements can strengthen the position of older people as active consumers, making their individual demands clearer. Older people needing care can be given a personal budget to purchase care from alternative competing agencies, or they and their families can be allowed to employ a personal care assistant directly and thereby be able to hire/fire, schedule, and supervise – in other words direct – care provision.

The Personal Budget scheme in the Netherlands is the largest of the schemes in this category. In 2003, 0.8 per cent of the population aged 65 or over received home care via a personal budget – compared with 7.4 per cent receiving some form of formal care at home (see columns to the right in Table 1, panel A).

In all of the programmes listed in Table 1, panel A, care assistants have a formal employment contract, even if they are relatives of the person receiving care. Therefore, care assistants are typically paid for a specified number of hours. They can provide care to several people at the same time and their wage does not depend on what income they have from other sources, as could an income-support payment. The level of care needs covered by these programmes varies typically from 3 to 10 hours per week for the Norwegian Care Wage and up to a maximum of 66 hours per week for the Californian In-home Supportive Services programme. In practice, however, relatives and friends employed as care assistants often provide care during more hours than they are paid for.

Personal budgets may also allow the person to combine care with purchase of physical aids such as a special bed or chair and can generally support very flexible solutions. This is one important aspect where the Cash & Counseling programme differs from other consumer-directed home care programmes in the United States.4 In the Netherlands, a limited amount can be made directly available to the person who does not need to account for how it is spent, and from this amount some informal help may also be compensated.5

The table includes information on the level of payments. Under this category of schemes the level of payments or public spending is roughly similar to what it would be for agency-based formal home care, as the care assistants employed by consumers in many schemes get an hourly wage similar to that of care assistants employed by agencies. For the US Cash & Counseling programme, the table shows the average monthly payment levels per person ranging from $400 in Arkansas to $1400 in New Jersey. To compare across countries with different currencies, this table shows the monthly payment levels also as a share of average private consumption per person. The $400 corresponds to 19.6 per cent of what an average person in the United States spends for private consumption per month (see Table 1, panel A).6

3.2 (B) Cash payments to the cared-for

Some countries give older people needing care the option of receiving cash to finance (part) of their expenditure on long-term care (Table 1, panel B). In Germany, people receiving support from long-term care insurance can choose between a budget for care services in-kind and the Cash Allowance for Care, and in Luxembourg those entitled to home care support under long-term care insurance may take part of this support as a cash benefit rather than services or everything as cash if found eligible for seven hours weekly or less. In Austria, all public support for long-term care to people living at home is given as cash. In practice, a substantial part of these cash payments is used to compensate informal caregivers or simply enters the household budget when care is provided by co-habiting relatives.

While there are no explicit restrictions on how the German Cash Allowance for Care is spent, the older person and their relatives are nevertheless obliged to acquire sufficient care. The health condition and wellbeing of recipients is reviewed every three or six months by an agency. If the older person is found to be receiving insufficient care in light of her/his needs then the authorities must find some provision of care services in-kind, in which case the cash allowance is withdrawn. For the UK Attendance Allowance, the requirements are looser as there are no restrictions on how the money can be spent, and it can be received even if the person does not obtain care from anyone. Provided the older person is at home (i.e., not in hospital or an institution) and has had the need for care for at least six months, she/he is eligible for the Attendance Allowance which is paid independently of the person's income and assets as for the other schemes listed in panels A and B.

Compared to schemes listed in panel A, most of the schemes listed in panel B are quite extensive. The Austrian and German schemes pay Cash Allowance for Care to 14.8 per cent and 5.7 per cent, respectively, of the population aged 65 or over. The payment levels vary considerably depending on need, with averages of 35 per cent and 27 per cent of private consumption per capita. When these payments are passed on to informal caregivers, they are in practice rarely taxed as income for the caregiver, as indeed the relation remains informal (often being within the family). The UK Attendance Allowance provides support to as many as the Austrian scheme but with a much lower maximum benefit paid.

3.3 (C) Income-support payments to informal caregivers

A number of OECD countries have various forms of payments to informal caregivers in order partly to compensate for the loss of income while providing care, thereby enabling the caregiver to reduce other work activities (Table 1, panel C). Some of these allowances or cash benefits pay around half of the average private consumption per person while the Swedish temporary Care Leave pays more than that. Other allowances, however, give only a limited supplement to the income of a household, such as the Japanese Allowance for Families Caring for Elderlypaying an amount equal to 5 per cent of average private consumption per person.7

The essential difference between consumer or client employment of a care assistant (reviewed in Table 1, panel A) is that income support is not meant to fully compensate caregivers for the value of their work. Rather, they are meant to sustain a minimum level of income for people who are unable to have a normal full-time job as a result of providing care for someone who is near to them such as a relative or close friend. Therefore, some schemes are only available for low-income carers, namely the Australian Carer Payment, the Irish Carer's Allowance, the Japanese Allowance for Families Caring for an Elderly and the UK Carer's Allowance. To be eligible for support, the income and asset criteria may also take into account the income and assets of the carer's spouse or partner and thereby exclude carers from middle- or high-income families. Also, payments from these schemes are often combined with other forms of public income support.8 Other schemes are built into labour market institutions and provide an option for temporary leave from work. As such they are available to people at all income levels. The Canadian Compassionate Care Benefit and the Swedish Care Leave replace 55 per cent and 80 per cent of the caregiver's previous or normal employment income up to a maximum, while the Irish Carer's Allowance pays the same amount to all recipients.

Finally, some schemes are meant to reward or recognise the efforts of all informal caregivers, as well as those caring for people with less severe needs (e.g., the Australian Carer Allowance). Eligibility is therefore conditional only on the provision of care, not on the income or assets of caregivers. Giving the limited amount of the Carer Allowance to a wide group of people living with, and caring for, an older person at home – equal in number to 4.0 per cent of the population aged 65 or more – creates an extra incentive for the family not to seek institutionalisation that would entail higher public expenditure.

In Japan, local authorities may decide whether they wish to use a central government grant to support informal care, including the Allowance for Families Caring for an Elderly Person. This allowance has been introduced very recently and is expected to play a minor role. The major policy direction is to expand in-kind benefits through Long-term Care Insurance (see chap. 5 in OECD 2005).

In the following, Section 4.1 discusses possible outcomes in terms of flexibility, care quality, satisfaction among people receiving long-term care and conditions for caregivers, whereas Section 4.2 addresses some of the implications for employment and fiscal sustainability. For a detailed assessment, including more quantitative evidence, see Lundsgaard (2005).

4.1 Implications for flexibility, user-perceived quality and satisfaction in long-term care

When people needing care have several options, their actual choices can give an indication of what works well for them as an individual and what best meets their needs, given the care policy context. The explicit choice between services in-kind and a cash payment or a combination of the two which is open to people receiving support from the German long-term care insurance is an interesting case, as older people have a right to choose and do not have to go through additional administrative procedures if desiring one option rather than the other. The outcome has been that initially only 8 per cent of those receiving care at home choose to have services in-kind only; the remainder choose cash only or a combination of cash and services (see Figure 3), despite the fact that the value of the cash awarded is lower than the value of the service benefit. And it is remarkable that this pattern is similar for people with very extensive care needs and people with fewer care needs (see Table 2). Since the introduction of the German long-term care insurance in 1991, the proportion choosing cash only has been declining gradually, but it is still above two-thirds.

Figure 3. 

Changing composition of choices over time in Germany. Source: Federal Statistical Office, Germany.

Figure 3. 

Changing composition of choices over time in Germany. Source: Federal Statistical Office, Germany.

Close modal
TABLE 2. 
Choices made by Germans supported by long-term care insurance, 1998.
Individuals choosing:Average share of cash for individuals choosing a combination of cash and services (%)
Cash onlyCombination of cash and servicesServices only
Proportion of individuals receiving support at each level (%)
A. Choice by level of care need 
1 – lowest 82  8 10 42 
2 – middle 77 13  9 35 
3 – highest 64 25  9 39 
     
B. Reasons stated by individuals receiving support for why they chose each form of support 
 Use cash for miscellaneous care needsDon't like to receive care from strangers Have some cash for miscellaneous tasksMore flexibility Can also giveinformal carers some payment No informal carer, or they don't have enough timeDon't want to be a burden on relativesState of health requires professional careRecommended by medical service  
Individuals choosing:Average share of cash for individuals choosing a combination of cash and services (%)
Cash onlyCombination of cash and servicesServices only
Proportion of individuals receiving support at each level (%)
A. Choice by level of care need 
1 – lowest 82  8 10 42 
2 – middle 77 13  9 35 
3 – highest 64 25  9 39 
     
B. Reasons stated by individuals receiving support for why they chose each form of support 
 Use cash for miscellaneous care needsDon't like to receive care from strangers Have some cash for miscellaneous tasksMore flexibility Can also giveinformal carers some payment No informal carer, or they don't have enough timeDon't want to be a burden on relativesState of health requires professional careRecommended by medical service  

Information in panel B is based on detailed telephone interviews of 1001 households receiving support, including both those aged over and under 65 years. Three-quarters of those receiving support from the German long-term care insurance are 65 or older.

Source: Schneekloth and Muller (2000).

In a number of other OECD countries, including Australia, the Netherlands, the United Kingdom and the United States, popularity among users has led to the growth of personal budgets, direct payments and consumer-directed home care schemes. For example in Australia, the Carer Payment available to people who, because of their caring responsibilities, are unable to participate in the workforce, has grown rapidly over recent years from 11,740 recipients caring for people aged 65 or more by June 1998 to 18,097 by June 2002. In Sweden, on the other hand, the option of being paid an Attendance Allowance for caring for a relative was taken up by only 4980 people in 2001 compared to 20,000 people about a decade ago, presumably because of the relatively higher coverage of publicly subsidised and high-quality home care.

These trends indicate that some older people find that the cash option is preferable to the service option. Whether this is a result of poor service quality, high user charges, lack of availability or stigma, we do not know. It could indicate a preference for choice between different sources of care, be it informal care provided by relatives or market care, and that the empowerment as consumers following from being able to choose among alternative public and non-public providers is appreciated because it increases flexibility and the control that older people have over their daily lives. As mentioned above, flexibility and self-determination are important since long-term care involves the most intimate aspects of a person's life. This is confirmed by a study of the outcome of the Personal Budget scheme in the Netherlands, which found that while care quality is roughly the same as when people needing care are referred administratively to a designated agency, people receiving care via a personal budget feel less dependent because they have more control over when care is provided and notably by whom (see Figure 4). Similar outcomes have been found in the Cash & Counseling pilots under Medicaid in the United States. Foster et al. (2003) conclude that relative to agency-directed care, consumer-directed care greatly improved satisfaction and reduced most unmet needs. To some extent, the flexibility aimed for with personal budgets can be achieved via the dialogue between the person needing care and the authorities assessing eligibility. In Norway, for example, the principle of allowing users to influence the care they receive is central to long-term care policy. People needing care can express their wishes but the final decision is made by representatives of the local government's agency.

Figure 4. 

Share having a positive assessment of the way care is delivered and the extent of choice in terms of the parameters listed. Note: the figure shows the responses from 668 individuals; 307 have a personal budget and of these 150 are assisted by a care consultant concerning the management of their budget; 361 are in the control group receiving administratively allocated care services. The background characteristics of these groups are similar. The sample includes both older people (the majority) and adult disabled (the minority) and covers holders of personal budgets for care and nursing as well as personal budgets for the mentally disabled. For all four items the difference between the assessment by individuals via a personal budget versus from administratively allocated services is statistically significant at a 0.1 per cent level. Source: Miltenburg and Ramakers (1999).

Figure 4. 

Share having a positive assessment of the way care is delivered and the extent of choice in terms of the parameters listed. Note: the figure shows the responses from 668 individuals; 307 have a personal budget and of these 150 are assisted by a care consultant concerning the management of their budget; 361 are in the control group receiving administratively allocated care services. The background characteristics of these groups are similar. The sample includes both older people (the majority) and adult disabled (the minority) and covers holders of personal budgets for care and nursing as well as personal budgets for the mentally disabled. For all four items the difference between the assessment by individuals via a personal budget versus from administratively allocated services is statistically significant at a 0.1 per cent level. Source: Miltenburg and Ramakers (1999).

Close modal

It could be asked whether leaving it in the hands of older people to find a care assistant to employ themselves would not imply a risk for vulnerable older people, particularly those with cognitive impairments, if they receive services from an untrained or possibly neglectful care assistant. How great such risks are may depend on many factors, including cultures and institutions in civil society that differ across countries. However, it is remarkable that the recent quality study of the Austrian Cash Allowance for Care – a system that goes further than in other OECD countries in leaving it to older people and their families to find appropriate care – did not find any cases of very poor hygiene or open neglect when surveying the condition of 700 older people with care needs greater than 120 hours per month. There may be other quality problems, but there is no indication of older people being neglected when relying on consumer-directed rather than agency-based care. Likewise, the experience from the Cash & Counseling pilots under Medicaid in the United States shows that consumer direction of care did not adversely affect participants’ health and safety (Foster et al. 2003). Apparently, the informal support and surveillance from relatives and others in the community is sufficient to avoid this. But it remains essential for public authorities to monitor the conditions of vulnerable older people, notably those without any remaining relatives.

Caring for a relative can be rewarding but also emotionally very demanding. In strategies to promote home- and community-based care it may therefore be desirable to have sufficient flexibility to support the type of arrangement that best suits the needs and wishes of different people – especially considering the enormous contribution from informal care resources to the overall pool of care. There are various ways in which support can reduce the strain of informal care giving. Financial support can reduce the need to maintain full-time paid work, thereby freeing up time for care giving. Likewise, some provision of formal care and home help can lift part of the burden off the informal caregiver. Notably, so-called respite care, which takes over for short periods of time, can allow the informal caregiver a break. Education of informal caregivers has been found to be another important field of support, as relatives becoming caregivers are not necessarily skilled in basic tasks such as how best to lift an immobile person in and out of bed. Informal caregivers can also benefit from better understanding the medical condition of the dependant. Support groups, often established by voluntary organisations, can contribute to this education and also provide informal caregivers with a forum for talking about the emotional strains arising from heavy care work. Finally, as pointed out by Lundh (1999), allowing informal caregivers to better enjoy the gains and positive aspects of caring for a relative can reduce emotional strains. The appropriate form of support depends on the type of informal care and who provides it. In the future, the role of children and grandchildren as informal caregivers may decrease and the role of spouses and other senior caregivers may increase, the latter group often having health problems themselves. This changing composition of the group of informal caregivers calls for new forms of care and possibly more support for informal caregivers.

Finally, as the motive for allowing more choice is to increase flexibility for users, it should not be expected that one particular scheme suits all older people needing long-term care. In particular, for older people with dementia the option of employing a care assistant themselves is of little relevance unless they have relatives or friends to act on their behalf by directing the work of the care assistant. And typically it is found that younger and adult disabled individuals are more interested in managing their care themselves. But there are many other dimensions aside from health conditions and age that matter; for example in Norway, the Care Wage is more frequently used in sparsely populated areas than in urban areas.

4.2 Getting value for money – implications for employment and fiscal sustainability

The long-term trends of ageing and changes in social relationships are likely to cause what some have called an ‘informal care crunch’ in many countries over the coming decades. The need for long-term care is likely to rise while the availability of informal care is likely to decline, as fewer older people live with their children and more of these children work and therefore cannot be expected to provide care to the same extent as daughters have done previously. How far this transition has gone varies significantly across OECD countries.9 It raises two strategic questions for the development of long-term care policies: who should be expected to provide care in the future? And should the people doing so be paid for it? Finding cost-effective answers to these questions is essential in the context of ageing and high demand and cost pressures elsewhere in health and social systems. Indeed, the economic rationale for paying informal caregivers depends much on their labour market attachment. However, the perspectives point in multiple directions:

  • For people who would otherwise be employed, payments for informal care, such as within a leave scheme, represent insurance against the loss of employment income they incur while providing care, and as insurance that they can return to the labour market, especially if there is a legal right to leave attached. Such payments allow families to choose informal care, and to the extent that such care replaces more expensive care that would have been provided formally and been publicly funded, the effect on public finances may be positive in the short run. Much, however, depends on the long-term labour market impacts. Particularly for those people with a loose attachment to the labour market, a prolonged period of leave can lead to subsequent unemployment as the person's skills or human capital may gradually deteriorate. Women in their 50s taking leave to care for a parent or parent-in-law may frequently be at risk in this regard.10 Very high payments to informal caregivers are therefore a mixed blessing by producing an unemployment or low-income trap that reduces the incentive for low-skilled people to maintain contact with the labour market. This problem is aggravated if payments for informal care can be received on top of unemployment benefits; cash payments to the people needing care make it essential to ensure that people receiving unemployment benefits are actively searching for regular employment in order to avoid a situation in which the combined income from unemployment benefits and some informal care giving exceeds what the person could obtain in a regular job. In leave schemes for informal caregivers, some countries confine the duration of leave to a limited period of time (such as during terminal illness) in order to avoid a situation in which caregivers loose touch with the formal labour market. Part-time leave may help carers maintain contact with the labour market; active assistance to help caregivers find work and a caregiver-friendly work culture are also important. Finally, promoting a market where quality care services can be purchased can help create new jobs and avoid forcing highly skilled people to leave their job to provide informal care, thereby reducing the return to individuals and society of their (often publicly funded) education.

  • For people who are more or less permanently outside employment and have other work income, such as retired people having a pension, care giving does not entail income loss and therefore there is no insurance argument for supporting informal care giving at home financially. However, to limit the need for costly formal long-term care services, some countries seek to mobilize and recognize informal caregivers for their work with payments, disregarding their labour market attachment and other income. Other countries find it essential not to engage in paying pensions to care for their relatives in order not to crowd out other spending that is more essential to maintaining a welfare society. The issue of recognising and supporting informal care giving has an important gender aspect, as most caregivers are women (Jenson and Jacobzone 2000).

There is a tendency for countries with extensive provision of formal home care but only limited financial support for informal care (such as the Scandinavian countries) to have higher employment rates for women aged 50–59 than, for example, the United Kingdom, Germany, Austria and Luxembourg which are countries in this study characterised by limited or average provision of formal home care but extensive financial support for informal care via cash allowances (see Figure 5). This finding is supported by studies using micro data which show that British informal caregivers bear costs, particularly in terms of lower wages, compared with others (Carmichael and Charles 1998,2003; Heitmueller and Inglis 2004). That is not to say, however, that more provision of formal home care services will automatically bring higher labour market participation rates. It is remarkable that among the Scandinavian countries, Sweden's employment rate for women aged 50–59 is higher than that of Norway and Denmark in both part-time and full-time jobs, despite providing publicly funded formal home care to only half as many older people as does Norway and Denmark.

Figure 5. 

Employment rates for women aged 50–59. Source: OECD, based on national labour force surveys.

Figure 5. 

Employment rates for women aged 50–59. Source: OECD, based on national labour force surveys.

Close modal

The question is: what is the cause and what is the effect? The lower employment rates of women aged 50–59 in countries such as Austria, Germany and Luxembourg probably to some extent reflect a cultural factor, reflecting a greater preference for living in one-earner couples. In this context, cash allowances may allow older individuals to acquire care from these people informally in a way that is much less costly to society than if formal services were to be provided. The Netherlands clearly shows that the availability of formal home care is not the only factor determining the employment rates of females in their 50s.

A particular concern is the adverse incentives for labour supply that can arise from programmes where people needing care are given cash, part of which they pass on to informal caregivers. Indeed, where the person needing care and the informal caregiver are living in the same household, a cash allowance for care naturally enters the common household budget. Also, if the informal caregiver is a close relative such as a daughter or son of the person needing care, the people involved may not think of passing on the money as something that should be reported to any authorities – and indeed tax and social security legislation may not take such payments into consideration. The consequence can be that the combination of taxation, unemployment benefits, social assistance and cash allowances for care redirected informally to the informal caregiver reduces the incentives for some unemployed people to actively search for employment while providing informal care for 15–20 hours a week, for example (Lundsgaard 2005).11

The type of choice arrangements for home care, the level of support they provide and the number of users were shown to vary enormously across and within OECD countries – reflecting also that long-term care provision differs more significantly across countries than acute health care systems. Choice arrangements (e.g., in the Netherlands) are preferred by a number of elderly people, where some report that they feel more satisfied and less dependent when having a say about how, when and notably by whom care is provided. Indications of shortfalls in care quality or outright neglect of frail older people were shown in one study to be remarkably rare, but informal caregivers – most being female – are known to carry sometimes large burdens in terms of physical pain and emotional strain from feelings of excessive responsibility, overload and isolation when working alone.

The implications for employment and fiscal sustainability are fairly complex. Giving older people a budget or cash to pay informal caregivers can help tap into a wider pool of human resources where there are shortages of professional care workers. On the other hand, a functioning market for formal home care services (or public supply of such services) is essential to allow relatives of older people in need of care to maintain their attachment to the normal labour market. And payments for informal care can risk creating ‘incentive traps’ that attract informal caregivers away from the normal labour market, if the interaction between informal care payments, taxes, unemployment benefits and other transfer incomes is not controlled well. After having been away from a normal job for a period of time, it can prove difficult to return.

Future ageing of populations together with demands for active ageing will increase the policy relevance of these issues. The large cohorts moving into old age in the coming decades may bring the fiscal sustainability of current health and long-term care systems into question. In this context, publicly funded formal home care, and, in particular, payments for informal care, will have to be carefully targeted. With more years in retirement, of which many are spent without major disabling conditions, the growing number of healthy and active senior citizens represents a potentially very valuable resource as informal caregivers. Finding the best way of nurturing this potential, and thereby shifting the task of providing informal care away from working-age children and towards able seniors (spouses, neighbours and others in the local community) may well prove to be key to achieving fiscal sustainability.

The preparation of this article has benefited from valuable comments and discussions with Manfred Huber and other members of the OECD Secretariat, including Martine Durand, Mark Pearson, Peter Scherer, Junichi Izumi, Patrick Hennessy, Weonjong Kim and Andres Fuentes, but first and foremost it would not have been possible to produce without the input from the representatives of the OECD member countries in the long-term care expert group and the Ad Hoc Group of the OECD Health Project. The article has also benefited from discussions with participants at the ‘Consumerism of Care for the Elderly’ symposium organised by the Danish National Institute of Social Research (SFI) in Copenhagen, August 2004, where an early draft was presented. The project has been funded partly by the Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation (ASPE), Department of Health and Human Services, in the United States.

1

This article reports the results of research on choice carried out as part of the long-term care study under the OECD Health Project. For more information about the OECD Health Project see www.oecd.org/health, where both the detailed report on the choice study (Lundsgaard 2005) and the final report on the wider long-term care study (OECD 2005) can be found.

2.

These countries are not covered in this study, but they are included here for comparison.

3.

See Lundsgaard (2003) for a comparison of how competition and choice is introduced in long-term care versus other publicly funded services.

4.

The Cash & Counseling Demonstration and Evaluation programme was started on the initiative of the federal government, with operations beginning in the three states in 1998–2000. The purpose is to test the limits of consumer direction via cash benefits allowing the people needing care more flexibility such as by substituting between care services, expenses for modifying their homes or vehicles, and purchase of items that help them live independently. See Doty (2000), Mahoney et al. (2000) and Foster et al. (2003).

5.

From April 2003, 1.5 per cent of the assigned budget does not need to be accounted for, between a minimum of €250 and a maximum of €1250 per year.

6.

Considering payment levels relative to private consumption rather than GDP per capita has several interesting interpretations for the purpose of the analysis in this article. In schemes where recipients receive cash, it shows how much or how little it is in an average household budget (for one person). Data for private consumption per person are derived from household final consumption expenditure per capita in the National Accounts.

7.

As several of these schemes are available only for low-income carers, however, the amounts could alternatively be compared to a lower level of private consumption than for an average person.

8.

In Australia, for example, informal caregivers can receive Carer Payment and Carer Allowance simultaneously if eligible for both. For example, a person aged 50 with low income who provides substantial care to, and lives with, her/his mother or father can receive both Carer Payment and Carer Allowance, corresponding to 64 per cent of average private consumption less taxes, but only Carer Payment if living separately, corresponding to 54 per cent of average private consumption less taxes. In both cases, other income-support payments may be added such as Rent Assistance.

9.

In the future, the availability of informal care may or may not continue to decline, depending on the country and a number of factors that are difficult to predict. In some OECD countries the factors that have historically reduced the availability of informal care can hardly go much further. For instance, in Sweden the share of older people living with their children is down at 4 per cent, as reported by Johansson (2000). In other OECD countries, the share is still considerably higher, but has been contracting. However, other groups of informal caregivers may take over. For England, Pickard et al. (2000) project that while the number of older people needing some form of care is likely to rise, a smaller share will be living alone by 2031 than was the case in 1996, as more will still have a spouse or partner living with them.

10.

Employment protection legislation may give people on leave who are providing informal care a right to come back to work, but this may create another problem as employers become less inclined to employ people who are likely to make use of leave schemes for informal long-term care, that is, women in their 50s.

11.

The adverse incentives analysed here are parallel to those arising when a person receiving unemployment benefits is working on the black market at the same time.

Carmichael
,
F.
, and
Charles
,
S.
,
1998
. ‘
The labour market costs of community care
’,
Journal of Health Economics
17
(
6
) (
1998
), pp.
747
65
.
Carmichael
,
F.
, and
Charles
,
S.
,
2003
. ‘
The opportunity costs of informal care: does gender matter?
’,
Journal of Health Economics
22
(
5
) (
2003
), pp.
781
803
.
Doty
,
P.
,
2000
. ‘
The federal role in the move toward consumer direction
’,
Generations
24
(
3
) (
2000
).
Foster
,
L.
,
Brown
,
R.
,
Philips
,
B.
,
Schore
,
J.
, and
Carlson
,
B. L.
,
2003
. ‘
Improving the quality of Medicaid personal assistance through consumer direction
’,
Health Affairs
(
2003
).
Heitmueller
,
A.
, and
Inglis
,
K.
,
2004
.
‘Carefree? Participation and pay differentials for informal carers in Britain’
, IZA Discussion Paper no. 1273, Available from, http://ftp.iza.org/dps/dp1273.pdf.
Jenson
,
J.
, and
Jacobzone
,
S.
,
2000
.
‘Care allowances for the frail elderly and their impact on women caregivers’
, Labour Market and Social Policy Occasional Article 41, OECD, Paris.
Johansson
,
L.
,
2000
. ‘
From policy to practice: the Swedish model
’. Presented at Paper presented at the 2nd International Conference on Caring.
Brisbane, Australia
, 29–31, March.
Lundh
,
U.
,
1999
. ‘
Family carers 4: designing services to support family carers in Sweden
’,
British Journal of Nursing
8
(
12
) (
1999
), pp.
787
90
.
Lundsgaard
,
J.
,
2003
.
‘Competition and efficiency in publicly funded services’
, OECD Economic Studies no. 35, OECD, Paris. Available from, http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/42/36/22027701.pdf.
Lundsgaard
,
J.
,
2005
.
‘Consumer direction and choice in long-term care for older persons, including payments for informal care – how can it help improve care outcomes, employment and fiscal sustainability?’
, OECD Health Working Paper. Available from, www.oecd.org/health.
Mahoney
,
K. J.
,
Simone
,
K.
, and
Simon-Rusinowitz
,
L.
,
2000
. ‘
Early lessons from the Cash and Counseling Demonstration and Evaluation
’,
Generations
24
(
3
) (
2000
).
1995
.
Millar
,
J.
, and
Warman
,
A.
, ed.
Defining Family Obligations in Europe.
Bath
:
University of Bath
;
1995
, eds, Bath Social Policy Papers no. 23.
Miltenburg
,
F. M.
, and
Ramakers
,
C. C.
,
1999
. ‘
Evaluatie-onderzoek persoonsgebonden budget in Nederland’ [Evaluation of personal care budgets in the Netherlands]
,
Tijdschrift voor gezondheidswetenschappen
77
(
7
) (
1999
).
2005
.
Long-term Care Policies for Older People
, Available from, www.oecd.org/health.
Pickard
,
L.
,
Wittenberg
,
R.
,
Comas Herrera
,
A.
,
Davies
,
B.
, and
Darton
,
R.
,
2000
. ‘
Relying on informal care in the new century? Informal care for elderly people in England to 2031
’,
Ageing and Society
20
(
2000
), pp.
745
72
.
Rostgaard
,
T.
,
2004
. ‘
With due care: social care for the young and the old across Europe
’. 2004, PhD thesis, Danish National Institute of Social Research, Copenhagen.
Schneekloth
,
U.
, and
Müller
,
U.
,
2000
.
Wirkungen der Pflegeversicherung
, [Effects of long-term care insurance].

Jens Lundsgaard is an economist at the OECD. His work concerns public finance, health and long-term care as well as economic policies more broadly. His current responsibility is to prepare the OECD Economic Surveys for the United Kingdom and Finland. As part of the OECD Health Project he has analysed the role of choice and support for informal care in OECD countries. It is the results of this analysis that are presented in this article. Before joining the OECD he worked for the Ministry of Finance in Denmark from 1998 to 2001.

This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 4.0 International (CC BY-NC 4.0) license, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the use is non-commercial and the original work is properly cited. For a full description of the license, please visit https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/4.0/legalcode.