Domestic policies are the cornerstone of the new global climate governance architecture. However, what motivates vote-seeking politicians to pursue climate policies remains remarkably unclear, as the climate politics literature suggests that climate policies are usually not perceived as a vote winner. The present article revisits this issue and argues that a better understanding of the relationship between electoral competition and climate policy making requires taking into account differences both in party ideologies and in policy characteristics. Studying twenty-nine democracies between 1990 and 2016, the analysis finds that climate policy production overall tends to increase as the election approaches due to increases in “soft” policies, such as subsidies, research grants, and information instruments, and relatively stable production rates of “hard” policies like taxes and regulations over the electoral term. Regarding partisan politics, left governments are found to produce more hard, but not more soft, climate policies than center and right governments, especially before elections. This suggests that partisan and electoral incentives are important reference points in the fight against climate change.

The new global climate governance architecture relies fundamentally on domestic policies. However, the current pledges are not sufficient to successfully limit global warming to 2°C, let alone 1.5°C (Rockström et al. 2017). Thus, to reach this collective goal, states must rapidly ratchet up the ambition of their national policies (Le Quéré et al. 2019). This situation stresses the need to better understand the motivations of national policy makers for producing climate policies.

Thanks to the growing literature, we already have some understanding of national climate policy making and its drivers (Bernauer 2013; Cao et al. 2014; Harrison and McIntosh Sundstrom 2007; Jordan et al. 2018; Purdon 2015). Comparative studies generally show growth in both the number and the ambition of national climate policies, as well as substantial cross-national differences (Bättig et al. 2008; Dubash et al. 2013; Schoenefeld et al. 2019). Such differences have been explained by, for instance, varying membership in international networks and learning effects (Hakelberg 2014; Hildén 2011; Tews et al. 2003) or the presence of democratic institutions, which are understood to provide more public goods than autocratic structures do (Bayer and Urpelainen 2016; Böhmelt et al. 2016). To explain climate policy variation among democracies, scholars have highlighted differences in citizen preferences and ideologies (Berry et al. 2015; Matisoff 2008); interest group strength (Cheon and Urpelainen 2013; Fredriksson et al. 2004); and types of institutions, economic organization, and governments (Bernhagen 2008; Dolšak 2001; Lachapelle and Paterson 2013; Schaffer and Bernauer 2014). Finally, there is growing evidence that political competition is key for understanding energy and climate policy making in democracies (Aklin and Urpelainen 2013; Breetz et al. 2018; Stokes 2016).

Despite these and additional advances, I see one important gap in climate politics research, namely, relating to the relationship between electoral competition and climate policy. Specifically, I see two unsettled questions in this context. The first is whether parties, and left–right differences in particular, matter for climate policy making, given that there is not much consensus on this point in the literature (Aklin and Urpelainen 2013; Fankhauser et al. 2015a; Garmann 2014; Harrison and McIntosh Sundstrom 2007; Jensen and Spoon 2011; Neumayer 2003; Tobin 2017; Ward and Cao 2012). The second question, which has so far received much less attention, is when governments and policy makers produce climate policy. In other words, we lack knowledge about whether and what kind of electoral cycles exist in the climate policy field. In fact, large-n studies dealing with electoral cycles in climate policy making do not seem to exist. However, a few large-n studies have included measures of the electoral calendar in their models. Interestingly, they have found either negative election effects, which imply negative electoral incentives associated with climate policy making (Aklin and Urpelainen 2013; Fankhauser et al. 2015a) or no effects at all, which could mean that climate policy is simply not very electorally salient (Garmann 2014). However, it is unclear to what extent these conclusions can be generalized. In particular, they appear remarkably at odds with the continuous increase in climate policies and legislation worldwide as well as increasing concern about climate change and support for climate policies among citizens (Capstick et al. 2015; McCright et al. 2015). This begs the question of whether governments and policy makers may after all (under certain conditions) pursue climate policies with a view to claiming political credit and attracting voters.

In this article, I revisit these two questions and highlight that to study the relationship between electoral competition and climate policy, it is important to consider not only partisan preferences and the electoral calendar but also the characteristics of the climate policies under study, a factor that has been widely overlooked in previous cross-national studies (especially large-n studies). In other words, the article highlights that partisan and electoral incentives will relate not only to the amount and timing of climate policy activity but also to its characteristics (Franzese 2002, 369). For this purpose, I distinguish between “hard” and “soft” climate policies. The former produce costs that are more visible and impose behavioral constraints or negative economic incentives, whereas the latter involve costs that are less visible and focus on positive economic incentives, information, or voluntary cooperation. These differences are expected to result in varying potential for mobilizing conflicting interests, leading to specific patterns of climate policy making across the electoral calendar and under different partisan compositions of government.

To test the arguments, I use comprehensive data on the production of national energy-related climate policies and measures in twenty-nine democracies between 1990 and 2016. Contrary to previous conclusions, the results show that climate policy making tends to increase as an election gets closer. This is due to soft policies, such as subsidies and informational instruments, which are introduced in greater numbers than hard policies like taxes and regulations—especially before elections. Regarding partisan politics, the results show that left governments generally introduce more climate policies than center and right governments. Most importantly, left governments are found to produce more hard, but not more soft, climate policies than center and right governments, especially before elections. This suggests that left governments are not only more willing than other governments to take the electoral risk of burdening voters with more visible costs of climate action but also may actually perceive such policies as an opportunity to win votes. Overall, the results demonstrate that parties matter in climate policy making and that positive electoral incentives are systematic features of this policy field.

Partisan and electoral cycles in public policy making arise as governments adjust their policy choices and the timing of their political action with a view to their constituents’ interests and their reelection prospects. Such patterns have long been identified for fiscal, economic, and social policy (Besley and Case 1995; Dubois 2016; Franzese 2002; Hibbs 1977; Nordhaus 1975; Potrafke 2017; Wehner 2013). However, whether similar patterns exist for climate policy making is not obvious. Classic partisan theory associates higher levels of state intervention and larger public sectors with left governments, while right governments pursue lower inflation and less government intervention (Hibbs 1977). Therefore, being generally more accustomed to intervening in the economy, left parties may also be expected to intervene more intensely on behalf of the climate and the environment. However, left parties could just as well be more cautious to pursue environmental and climate policies because they tend to increase costs for heavy-polluting industries that employ a significant share of workers—their traditional core constituency (King and Borchardt 1994). Similarly, if energy demand is inelastic, rising energy prices will tend to hurt workers more than capital owners and thus be more harmful to the voter base of left parties (Garmann 2014, 2).

Such ambivalent arguments have led scholars to study whether policy makers’ environmental policy preferences cut across the left–right spectrum of party competition and whether they influence environmental policy making (Bäck et al. 2015; Carter 2013; Dalton 2009; Facchini et al. 2017; Jahn 2016; Neumayer 2003, 2004; Schulze 2014). Interestingly, for climate policy making more specifically, the empirical evidence is fairly divided. Some studies have associated left governments with more climate policies and better climate performance (Garmann 2014; Neumayer 2003; Tobin 2017), while others fail to identify significant ideological differences or stress the importance of environmental policy preferences (Bayer and Urpelainen 2016; Jensen and Spoon 2011; Ward and Cao 2012).

Despite a divided empirical literature, there are, arguably, plausible reasons to expect that left–right differences matter for climate policy making. To this end, let us reconsider the formation of parties’ climate policy preferences in more detail—especially the role of public opinion, party competition, and existing policy preferences—and how these mechanisms relate to the left–right dimension (see Ladrech and Little 2019). First, surveys consistently show that public opinion on climate change matches fairly well with individuals’ left–right orientation, with the left usually expressing greater concern about a changing climate and greater willingness to act on measures for its protection (Dunlap et al. 2016; Hornsey et al. 2016; McCright et al. 2015). Thus, partisan differences along the left–right dimension may be expected if policy makers are responsive to this uneven preference allocation. Interviewing policy makers and experts from Ireland and Denmark, Ladrech and Little (2019) find supporting evidence that an uneven distribution of climate concern has indeed influenced parties’ climate policy preferences and strategies, with left-of-center parties being particularly aware of their more concerned constituents. Second, parties are generally more inclined to attract voters from parties that are closer to them on a particular dimension (Adams and Somer-Topcu 2009). The greatest electoral challenge on the climate change issue arguably comes from green parties, which are still the party family with the most pro-environment policy positions (Carter 2013; Neumayer 2004). Green parties are also, with a few exceptions, closer to the left, so they arguably pose a greater threat to traditional left parties. We can thus expect that other left parties show stronger accommodative behavior and more climate policy activity in response to successful green parties (issue owners) than do parties on the right (Fagerholm 2016; Jahn and Korolczuk 2012; Kitschelt 1994; Spoon et al. 2014). Third, it is well known that responding to climate change requires particularly rapid and profound transformations of national economies and individual lifestyles and thus substantial state-led interventions. Left governments are specifically known for more interventionist policies, and left voters tend to expect these policies from their representatives. Thus, existing policy preferences associated with traditional left–right politics may induce left governments to become more active in climate policy making than other governments (Båtstrand 2014; Ladrech and Little 2019). Finally, research suggests that climate policy involves more positional disagreement and stronger alignment with the left–right dimension than does environmental policy more generally, the latter arguably being closer to a valence issue (Carter et al. 2018; Farstad 2018). If this is the case, we can also expect that left–right differences are more likely to manifest in climate policy making. In summary, facing more concerned voters and a greater electoral threat from green parties, as well as expectations for more state intervention in a politicized policy field, left governments can be expected to experience stronger electoral incentives to pursue climate policies than other governments. This leads to the first hypothesis:

H1: The introduction of climate policies becomes more likely under a left government.

Although the issues of electoral cycles and partisan politics are closely intertwined, there is much less empirical work concerning the effect of the electoral calendar on climate policy making. The general expectation of electoral cycles in public policy making goes back to Nordhaus (1975), who argued that incumbent governments are likely to boost output and lower unemployment in pre-election periods to maximize their chances of reelection. Subsequent work has stressed that the existence and shape of electoral cycles may depend on many other factors, such as partisan preferences, information asymmetries, and institutional limitations (De Haan and Klomp 2013; Dubois 2016).

However, when is a good time for governments to pursue climate policies? Assuming that climate policies place a constraint on domestic economic actors, new climate policies may induce electoral incentives akin to the introduction of a new tax or charge. The latter are known to be less frequently introduced before elections if reelection is at stake (Besley and Case 1995). Moreover, if the industrial sector is more strongly affected by climate policies, this tendency may be reinforced. As Cazals and Sauquet (2015, 266) note, the industrial sector is typically represented by particularly important lobbies that provide campaign contributions and many jobs to workers that may become threatened by new constraints. Under the threat of losing these votes and substantial lobby support, governments may strive to delay climate policy making to postelection periods that are less critical.

Recent studies have found evidence in line with these arguments. For example, Fankhauser et al. (2015a, 59) find a negative interaction effect between a democracy variable and election year on the passage of climate legislation and therefore argue that “climate legislation is not generally seen as a vote winner” in democracies. Aklin and Urpelainen (2013) find that the election year exerts a negative influence on the growth of renewable energy shares. Finally, Cazals and Sauquet (2015) find that democratic countries are less likely to ratify international environmental agreements in the pre-election period, while the opposite holds true for autocracies.

As already mentioned, these findings of negative electoral incentives stand in marked contrast with the ever-increasing amount of climate policy worldwide as well as increasing climate concerns of citizens, particularly among democracies. This begs the question of whether the pursuit of climate policies is in fact predominantly unpopular for vote-seeking politicians and whether it is even possible to identify systematic efforts by policy makers to win votes through more active climate policy making. List and Sturm (2006) offer support for a similar conjecture, finding that US governors strategically manipulate environmental policies when their reelections are at stake to attract additional voters. Similarly, McAlexander and Urpelainen (2020) find that both Democratic and Republican legislators are more likely to cast pro-environment votes before an election, catering to a public that is generally in favor of environmental policies.

However, given that the empirical evidence so far predominantly associates climate policy making with negative electoral incentives, I state the second hypothesis in this way and put it up to the empirical test:

H2: The introduction of climate policies becomes less likely as the election approaches.

The next section discusses conditions under which positive electoral incentives may be more likely.

Policy characteristics are an established driver of environmental policy innovation and diffusion—usually alongside domestic and international factors (Jordan et al. 2013; Tews et al. 2003). However, despite recent advances (e.g., Hughes and Urpelainen 2015; Madden 2014; Matisoff and Edwards 2014; Pahle et al. 2018), the potential of policy characteristics for understanding climate policy change and diffusion has yet to be used to full capacity (Jordan and Huitema 2014, 724; Keohane 2015; see also Makse and Volden 2011).

To incorporate policy characteristics into our understanding of how partisan and electoral competition affects climate policy making, I rely on established policy literature distinguishing between different policy instruments and governance principles. The primary goal is to derive testable hypotheses about how policy choice relates to electoral competition. I therefore opt for a parsimonious and substantive rather than procedural distinction between “hard” and “soft” climate policies grounded in the taxonomy of policy instruments established by Vedung (1998) and extended by Steurer (2011) (see also Schaffrin et al. 2015). The taxonomy distinguishes between regulatory (“sticks”), economic (“carrots”), informational (“sermons”), cooperative (“ties”), and organizational (“adhesives”) policy instruments. This model is appropriate for the present analysis because the starting point for the distinctions is the relationship between public authorities and private actors and the degree of authoritative force (see also Sager 2009, 539–540). In the following, I draw on this basis to conceptualize the relationship between governments and voters in climate policy making.

The main argument is that different climate policies can be broadly placed into two categories—hard and soft—based on their degree of authoritative force, which can be associated with the visibility of the costs they produce. Hard climate policies include bans and regulations (“command-and-control” instruments), which aim to control the behavior of citizens and firms by limiting their choices. For instance, emissions standards define the spheres of legal versus illegal behavior and lead to directly visible costs for the addressees, for example, car industries (Meckling and Nahm 2018). In contrast, economic policy instruments do not require addressees to change their behavior, but they establish positive and negative incentives to achieve such changes. However, different types of economic instruments vary in their emphasis of these incentives. I therefore depart from previous studies (see Schaffrin et al. 2015; Steurer 2011) and do not place carbon taxes and tradable permit schemes in the same category as other economic and financial instruments, such as subsidies and tax rebates. Rather, the former are considered hard policies because they usually involve negative economic incentives, punishing carbon-intensive behavior, and highly visible costs that can invoke considerable opposition from large, well-organized groups of heavy emitters of greenhouse gases (Madden 2014, 6; see also Shwom et al. 2010).

Soft climate policies, by contrast, impose costs that are less visible to voters and organized interests, mainly because they are paid through the general revenue system.1 This includes soft economic instruments, which emphasize positive financial incentives rewarding carbon-saving behavior. Subsidies and tax rebates for the purchase of solar panels or energy efficient retrofits, as well as research grants for the development of climate-friendly technologies, fall into this category. Such policies can also create an electoral advantage by stimulating supporter coalitions, such as low-carbon industries, through quickly generating and distributing benefits and investing in localized capital. These specific beneficiaries may later become important allies in the political struggle for “harder” climate policies (Jacobs 2016; Pahle et al. 2018). Soft policies also include informational tools, such as energy-efficiency labels or campaigns, that essentially aim to transfer enough knowledge to induce the desired behavior. Finally, voluntary agreements between industry and government as well as institutions and strategies supporting policy implementation can also be considered soft policies (Steurer 2011). In general, the characteristics of soft policies can be expected to involve less controversial policy processes or, as Madden (2014, 7) outlined, to produce costs that are diffuse enough to avoid strong opposition.

However, what kind of policy-making patterns can be associated with hard and soft climate policies? Generally, soft policies should outnumber hard policies because policy makers from almost all camps seek to signal their commitment to climate protection and distribute specific benefits while minimizing electoral risks. Soft policies may be also more prevalent simply because they elicit less opposition and therefore make it easier to achieve necessary consent in the domestic policy process. However, apart from this general pattern, the two types of policies may be associated with diverging electoral cycles. On one hand, we should see more soft policies as the election gets closer, given that, in most countries, a majority of the public generally supports climate change policies (McCright et al. 2015), and policy makers therefore seek to increase their demonstration of climate activism (see List and Sturm 2006; McAlexander and Urpelainen 2020). In this case, softer policies will be the preferred choice, as they offer an opportunity to avoid blame through less visible costs and to claim credit for specific benefits.2 On the other hand, policy makers should eschew hard climate policies as the election gets closer to avoid strong opposition and punishment at the polls. To be sure, I understand that policy makers also pursue hard policies (for whatever reasons) but prefer not to highlight them in the run-up to elections. This leads to the next hypothesis:

H3: The introduction of hard (soft) climate policies becomes less (more) likely as the election approaches.

Having incorporated policy characteristics into expectations on electoral cycles, we now need to reconsider partisan incentives. The general argument was that left governments have stronger electoral incentives to introduce climate policies than other governments. To demonstrate greater climate activism, left governments could therefore also produce more hard climate policies (along with soft policies), precisely because they are more visible and therefore send a stronger signal to voters who are more concerned about climate change. Moreover, left parties’ existing policy preferences for more state intervention are generally more in line with hard climate policies than those of other parties (Båtstrand 2014). Overall, I therefore expect that not only will left governments be more willing than other governments to impose more visible costs upon voters but they may actually perceive hard climate policies as an opportunity to win additional votes and prevent voter loss to green parties. Second, if this is the case, it is also plausible to expect that left governments will not only not bother delaying the introduction of hard climate policies until after the election but may actually increase the production of hard policies ahead of it (in addition to increasing the production of soft climate policies). However, I would not expect stark partisan differences for soft climate policies because the latter are more likely to attract voters and parties from the left and right alike. This leads to the final hypothesis:

H4: The introduction of hard climate policies becomes more likely under a left government, especially as the election approaches.

There is an ongoing debate on how to measure climate policy and its changes (see, e.g., Dupuis and Biesbroek 2013; Knill et al. 2012; Schaffrin et al. 2015). Here, I use the International Energy Agency’s (IEA) Policies and Measures Database, which covers past and existing energy-related government policies and measures aimed at reducing greenhouse gas emissions for all IEA member states and a number of additional countries (see also Cao and Ward 2016; Hughes and Urpelainen 2015). The country sample is restricted to IEA member states, as their governments had the opportunity to regularly review the data (in contrast to non-IEA members). The analysis therefore includes all twenty-nine IEA member states (as of 2016) observed from 1990 through 2016.3 This amounts to 783 country-years, of which 183 have no policy activities and 600 have at least one climate policy introduced at the national level.

As summarized in Table 1, I distinguish between hard and soft climate policies using the IEA’s categorization of policies into different types and subtypes. Hard policies include climate-related taxes and carbon trading mechanisms, user charges, codes and standards, and general auditing and monitoring schemes,4 which all impose directly visible costs for private actors. In contrast, soft policies include direct investments, grants and subsidies, policy development and reform, informational tools, and voluntary approaches, all involving costs that are less visible. As the IEA database can assign policies to several types, the coding process started off with classifying a policy as “soft” only if it does not simultaneously belong to any of the policy subtypes defined as “hard.” In a second step, all the (prima facie) hard policies were reviewed to check whether they are in fact hard policies according to the outlined arguments. This led to the reclassification of several policies as soft, such as industry codes and standards that are voluntary. Moreover, policies that are predominantly soft but have some hard elements attached, for example, research funds and demonstration projects where recipients are audited and monitored were reclassified.5

Table 1

Two Categories of Climate Policies

Hard Climate PoliciesSoft Climate Policies
Regulatory instruments and economic instruments with negative incentives. Costs are more visible (directly borne by firms and individuals). Economic instruments focusing on positive incentives, public investments, organization, informational and voluntary instruments. Costs are less visible (mainly paid through the general budget). 
  • Taxes and tradable permit schemes

  • User charges

  • Codes and standards (building codes and product standards, sectoral standards, vehicle fuel-economy and emissions standards)

  • Obligation schemes and other mandatory requirements

  • Mandatory auditing and monitoring schemes

 
  • Direct investments, grants and subsidies, loans, tax relief

  • Policy development and reform (policy support, including institutional creation and strategic planning)

  • Research, development, and deployment (RD&D) (including demonstration projects, research programs for technology deployment and diffusion and for technology development)

  • Information and education (including advice/aid in implementation, information provision, performance labels, professional training and qualification)

  • Voluntary approaches (negotiated agreements between public–private sector, public voluntary schemes, unilateral commitments by private sector)

 
Hard Climate PoliciesSoft Climate Policies
Regulatory instruments and economic instruments with negative incentives. Costs are more visible (directly borne by firms and individuals). Economic instruments focusing on positive incentives, public investments, organization, informational and voluntary instruments. Costs are less visible (mainly paid through the general budget). 
  • Taxes and tradable permit schemes

  • User charges

  • Codes and standards (building codes and product standards, sectoral standards, vehicle fuel-economy and emissions standards)

  • Obligation schemes and other mandatory requirements

  • Mandatory auditing and monitoring schemes

 
  • Direct investments, grants and subsidies, loans, tax relief

  • Policy development and reform (policy support, including institutional creation and strategic planning)

  • Research, development, and deployment (RD&D) (including demonstration projects, research programs for technology deployment and diffusion and for technology development)

  • Information and education (including advice/aid in implementation, information provision, performance labels, professional training and qualification)

  • Voluntary approaches (negotiated agreements between public–private sector, public voluntary schemes, unilateral commitments by private sector)

 

Source: Author’s elaboration based on IEA (2020).

Following this distinction, the data set identifies 388 hard and 1,733 soft national climate policies. Following the theoretical arguments, the focus is on the number, or “density,” of different types of policies and not their content or expected outcomes. However, this also means that the analysis does not distinguish further between different levels of policy “intensity,” for example, different tax or grant levels.6Figure 1 presents the cumulative number of climate policies aggregated over the country sample and shows rapid growth, especially since the late 1990s. Figure 2 presents the national stocks of hard and soft policies introduced across the countries under study as of 2016. The largest overall stock of energy-related climate policies (211 policies) exists in the United States. The Czech Republic, by contrast, has only introduced twenty-six policies, while the sample average is approximately seventy-three policies.

Figure 1

Cumulative Number of Climate Policies in Twenty-Nine IEA Member States, 1990–2016

Figure 1

Cumulative Number of Climate Policies in Twenty-Nine IEA Member States, 1990–2016

Close modal
Figure 2

National Stocks of Climate Policies in 2016

Figure 2

National Stocks of Climate Policies in 2016

Close modal

Table 2 gives a first impression regarding the main research questions by showing the mean number of climate policy introductions over the course of the electoral term and different types of government. I identify left, center, and right governments based on the Seki–Williams measure of the partisan complexion of government (2014), which is an updated version of the Woldendorp et al. (2000) index, placing governments on an ideological scale between 1 and 5. I define right governments as marked by either right party dominance or right-center complexion in government and parliament (index values of 1 and 2), center governments by a balanced situation (index value of 3), and left governments by either left-center complexion or left party dominance (index values of 4 and 5).7 In this context, one drawback of the yearly periodization of the data set should be noted; namely, for election years, it cannot precisely identify whether a given policy was introduced before or after the election date. As the Seki-Williams measure is also a weighted average in election years, I use the index values for the dominant context in these years. Therefore, the results for the election year should generally be taken with a grain of salt.

Table 2

Climate Policy Introductions by Years Left in the Electoral Term in Twenty-Nine IEA Member States, 1990–2016

YearsAll GovernmentsLeft GovernmentsCenter GovernmentsRight Governments
MeanSELowerUpperMeanSELowerUpperMeanSELowerUpperMeanSELowerUpper
All Policies 
2.82 0.30 2.22 3.42 3.52 0.61 2.30 4.75 2.11 0.33 1.45 2.77 2.99 0.56 1.86 4.11 
3.14 0.27 2.60 3.67 3.53 0.54 2.44 4.62 3.46 0.64 2.16 4.77 2.67 0.32 2.03 3.30 
2.68 0.19 2.30 3.05 2.92 0.35 2.21 3.62 2.64 0.36 1.92 3.37 2.52 0.30 1.94 3.11 
2.57 0.21 2.16 2.98 2.60 0.34 1.93 3.27 2.91 0.42 2.06 3.76 2.31 0.33 1.65 2.97 
1.91 0.33 1.26 2.56 3.00 0.90 1.03 4.97 1.83 0.76 0.17 3.50 1.52 0.35 0.80 2.24 
All years 2.71 0.12 2.48 2.94 3.11 0.22 2.67 3.55 2.66 0.21 2.25 3.07 2.49 0.18 2.15 2.84 
Hard Policies 
0.43 0.06 0.31 0.54 0.75 0.17 0.41 1.09 0.32 0.09 0.14 0.50 0.32 0.07 0.18 0.45 
0.51 0.07 0.38 0.64 1.05 0.16 0.74 1.37 0.15 0.07 0.01 0.29 0.28 0.06 0.16 0.40 
0.52 0.06 0.41 0.63 0.73 0.12 0.50 0.97 0.53 0.12 0.30 0.77 0.36 0.06 0.23 0.49 
0.56 0.06 0.44 0.68 0.65 0.12 0.41 0.89 0.56 0.11 0.35 0.77 0.49 0.09 0.32 0.66 
0.44 0.09 0.25 0.62 0.58 0.29 0.08 1.09 0.50 0.23 −0.01 1.01 0.36 0.11 0.13 0.58 
All years 0.50 0.03 0.44 0.55 0.79 0.08 0.65 0.92 0.41 0.05 0.31 0.50 0.36 0.03 0.29 0.42 
Soft Policies 
2.40 0.292 1.83 2.96 2.77 0.53 1.70 3.84 1.79 0.30 1.19 2.39 2.67 0.56 1.56 3.78 
2.63 0.25 2.13 3.13 2.47 0.48 1.52 3.43 3.31 0.65 2.00 4.62 2.39 0.30 1.78 2.99 
2.16 0.18 1.81 2.50 2.18 0.31 1.57 2.80 2.11 0.32 1.48 2.75 2.16 0.28 1.60 2.72 
2.01 0.19 1.64 2.38 1.95 0.31 1.33 2.56 2.35 0.40 1.56 3.15 1.81 0.29 1.25 2.38 
1.47 0.30 0.88 2.06 2.42 0.76 0.74 4.10 1.33 0.66 −0.11 2.76 1.16 0.34 0.46 1.86 
All years 2.21 0.11 2.00 2.42 2.32 0.19 1.94 2.71 2.26 0.20 1.87 2.65 2.13 0.17 1.80 2.47 
YearsAll GovernmentsLeft GovernmentsCenter GovernmentsRight Governments
MeanSELowerUpperMeanSELowerUpperMeanSELowerUpperMeanSELowerUpper
All Policies 
2.82 0.30 2.22 3.42 3.52 0.61 2.30 4.75 2.11 0.33 1.45 2.77 2.99 0.56 1.86 4.11 
3.14 0.27 2.60 3.67 3.53 0.54 2.44 4.62 3.46 0.64 2.16 4.77 2.67 0.32 2.03 3.30 
2.68 0.19 2.30 3.05 2.92 0.35 2.21 3.62 2.64 0.36 1.92 3.37 2.52 0.30 1.94 3.11 
2.57 0.21 2.16 2.98 2.60 0.34 1.93 3.27 2.91 0.42 2.06 3.76 2.31 0.33 1.65 2.97 
1.91 0.33 1.26 2.56 3.00 0.90 1.03 4.97 1.83 0.76 0.17 3.50 1.52 0.35 0.80 2.24 
All years 2.71 0.12 2.48 2.94 3.11 0.22 2.67 3.55 2.66 0.21 2.25 3.07 2.49 0.18 2.15 2.84 
Hard Policies 
0.43 0.06 0.31 0.54 0.75 0.17 0.41 1.09 0.32 0.09 0.14 0.50 0.32 0.07 0.18 0.45 
0.51 0.07 0.38 0.64 1.05 0.16 0.74 1.37 0.15 0.07 0.01 0.29 0.28 0.06 0.16 0.40 
0.52 0.06 0.41 0.63 0.73 0.12 0.50 0.97 0.53 0.12 0.30 0.77 0.36 0.06 0.23 0.49 
0.56 0.06 0.44 0.68 0.65 0.12 0.41 0.89 0.56 0.11 0.35 0.77 0.49 0.09 0.32 0.66 
0.44 0.09 0.25 0.62 0.58 0.29 0.08 1.09 0.50 0.23 −0.01 1.01 0.36 0.11 0.13 0.58 
All years 0.50 0.03 0.44 0.55 0.79 0.08 0.65 0.92 0.41 0.05 0.31 0.50 0.36 0.03 0.29 0.42 
Soft Policies 
2.40 0.292 1.83 2.96 2.77 0.53 1.70 3.84 1.79 0.30 1.19 2.39 2.67 0.56 1.56 3.78 
2.63 0.25 2.13 3.13 2.47 0.48 1.52 3.43 3.31 0.65 2.00 4.62 2.39 0.30 1.78 2.99 
2.16 0.18 1.81 2.50 2.18 0.31 1.57 2.80 2.11 0.32 1.48 2.75 2.16 0.28 1.60 2.72 
2.01 0.19 1.64 2.38 1.95 0.31 1.33 2.56 2.35 0.40 1.56 3.15 1.81 0.29 1.25 2.38 
1.47 0.30 0.88 2.06 2.42 0.76 0.74 4.10 1.33 0.66 −0.11 2.76 1.16 0.34 0.46 1.86 
All years 2.21 0.11 2.00 2.42 2.32 0.19 1.94 2.71 2.26 0.20 1.87 2.65 2.13 0.17 1.80 2.47 

Column 1 reports the mean number of climate policy introductions for the number of years left in the electoral term. Column 2 gives the standard error (SE). Columns 3 and 4 report the upper and lower bounds of 95 percent confidence intervals.

The first thing to note is that the mean of all policies is highest in the year before an election, is second highest in the election year, and decreases if two or more years are left in the electoral term. This runs counter to the expectation that approaching elections exert a negative effect on climate policy making. If anything, this finding hints at positive incentives for introducing climate policies as the election approaches. Neither do these descriptive results suggest that hard climate policies are less likely to be introduced in the run-up to elections. At best, there appears to be a rather small decrease over the electoral term. In contrast, Table 2 shows that soft policies are, on average, more likely to be introduced in the year before an election (mean number of policies of 2.63) than in all other years of the electoral term, especially when compared to nonelection years. Thus, in general, there might be a positive electoral incentive to introduce soft climate policies, while the situation appears to be more complex for hard policies. The following parts concentrate on government ideology as a potential conditioning factor.

Inspecting the distribution of policy production under different partisan governments, the mean number for both hard and soft policies is generally highest under left governments, followed by center and right governments. Most interestingly, the mean number of hard climate policies tends to increase under left governments as the election approaches, while the exact opposite pattern can be observed for center and right governments. Thus, the relatively stable production rates of hard policies over the electoral term are in fact a result of opposing trends across different types of partisan government. Notably, there is no such partisan discrepancy in the production of soft policies, which tend to increase under all types of partisan government as the election approaches. I continue with multiple regression analysis to control for various other factors that may also affect climate policy production.

Control Variables

The first control variable denotes the participation of a green party in government, as this party family may have a particularly strong policy impact on climate policy making once in office. Second, the parliamentary seat share of green parties controls for the electoral threat from green issue owners and any policy effect associated with their role in parliament (Jensen and Spoon 2011). Third, an indicator of majority government takes into account that minority governments might have to secure additional parliamentary support to introduce climate policies. Fourth, the degree of institutional and political constraints (veto players) may also affect climate policy making. Therefore, the widely used index developed by Henisz (2000) is included. Next, climate policy-making may be subject to nonlinear path dependencies as existing climate policies first stimulate more policy making but later decrease the need for further policies because aspects are increasingly already addressed (Fankhauser et al. 2015a). This is taken into account by including domestic stocks of climate policy introductions and their square term. In this, I test whether stocks of soft climate policies pave the way for more hard policies, as the sequencing literature argues. Finally, there might be a (perceived) trade-off between climate policies and economic growth as well as a propensity of richer countries to introduce more climate policies. GDP growth rates and the GDP per capita are included to capture such effects.

A last set of controls refers to international influences. First, I control for IEA membership, as some member states have only joined the IEA during the observation period. Second, the EU’s potential impact on national climate policy is considered by distinguishing members and nonmembers (Avrami and Sprinz 2019; Schreurs and Tiberghien 2007). Third, a dummy variable is included that takes on a value of 1 for countries hosting a UN climate conference (COP) in the year of the meeting and the subsequent two years (Fankhauser et al. 2015b) as well as a dummy variable indicating whether a country has ratified the Kyoto Protocol. Finally, other countries’ climate policies can create stimuli (diffusion mechanisms) for countries to follow suit. The average stock of climate policies introduced among a given country’s neighboring IEA members is added to control for such effects.

Estimation Issues

The dependent variable is a positive count of national energy-related climate policies introduced over each year. The standard analytical approach in this situation would be to estimate negative binomial regression models. Country and year fixed effects would moreover account for time-invariant unobserved country characteristics, such as electoral rules and temporal dynamics like technological advances or growing public concern about climate change. Using country-fixed effects would also be feasible given substantial within-country variation in policy introductions (standard deviation of 2.8) exceeding between-country variation (standard deviation of 1.65). Unfortunately, there is no generally recommended fixed effects negative binomial estimator (Allison and Waterman 2002). I therefore follow recent examples (Bove and Böhmelt 2016; Gleditsch and Polo 2016) and log transform the dependent variable after adding 1, which allows one to run linear panel regressions with country and year dummies. Table 3 shows the main results.8

Table 3

Climate Policy Production in Twenty-Nine IEA Member States, 1990–2016

 All PoliciesHard PoliciesSoft Policies
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Left government 0.192** 0.190** 0.212*** 0.212*** 0.087 0.085 
(0.075) (0.075) (0.038) (0.039) (0.078) (0.078) 
Years left in term −0.017   0.018   −0.030   
(0.020)   (0.013)   (0.021)   
Years left in term = 0   0.076   −0.014   0.102 
  (0.105)   (0.068)   (0.122) 
Years left in term = 1   0.105   0.001   0.111 
  (0.106)   (0.074)   (0.125) 
Years left in term = 2   0.063   0.032   0.053 
  (0.100)   (0.077)   (0.122) 
Years left in term = 3   0.046   0.059   0.018 
  (0.105)   (0.069)   (0.120) 
Greens in government −0.135 −0.130 0.050 0.051 −0.196*** −0.193*** 
(0.080) (0.082) (0.095) (0.096) (0.064) (0.064) 
Green seats −0.008 −0.007 −0.005 −0.004 −0.009 −0.009 
(0.021) (0.021) (0.010) (0.010) (0.020) (0.020) 
Majority government 0.001 0.000 −0.028 −0.029 −0.005 −0.005 
(0.098) (0.099) (0.061) (0.061) (0.091) (0.091) 
Political constraints 0.351 0.341 −0.247 −0.257 0.326 0.322 
(0.426) (0.424) (0.275) (0.279) (0.432) (0.432) 
Domestic stocka 0.010** 0.010** −0.001 −0.001 0.014*** 0.014*** 
(0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) 
Domestic stock2,a −0.000** −0.000** 0.000** 0.000** −0.000*** −0.000*** 
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) 
GDP growth 0.009 0.009 0.006 0.006 0.006 0.006 
(0.009) (0.009) (0.004) (0.004) (0.011) (0.011) 
GDP p.c. (log) 0.100 0.103 −0.007 −0.004 0.107 0.107 
(0.080) (0.078) (0.034) (0.033) (0.073) (0.071) 
IEA member 0.120 0.121 0.117* 0.117* 0.054 0.055 
(0.146) (0.146) (0.059) (0.060) (0.159) (0.159) 
COP host 0.196 0.188 0.028 0.021 0.223 0.220 
(0.139) (0.143) (0.078) (0.077) (0.150) (0.153) 
Kyoto ratification −0.156 −0.151 0.091 0.092 −0.265* −0.262* 
(0.182) (0.182) (0.080) (0.081) (0.150) (0.151) 
EU member −0.066 −0.066 −0.058 −0.058 −0.028 −0.029 
(0.184) (0.184) (0.097) (0.097) (0.186) (0.186) 
Diffusion (neighbors) −0.000 −0.000 0.002* 0.002* −0.001 −0.001 
(0.002) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) 
Observations 768 768 768 768 768 768 
Log likelihood −618.545 −618.190 −343.896 −343.121 −626.950 −626.706 
R2 0.469 0.469 0.231 0.233 0.453 0.454 
 All PoliciesHard PoliciesSoft Policies
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Left government 0.192** 0.190** 0.212*** 0.212*** 0.087 0.085 
(0.075) (0.075) (0.038) (0.039) (0.078) (0.078) 
Years left in term −0.017   0.018   −0.030   
(0.020)   (0.013)   (0.021)   
Years left in term = 0   0.076   −0.014   0.102 
  (0.105)   (0.068)   (0.122) 
Years left in term = 1   0.105   0.001   0.111 
  (0.106)   (0.074)   (0.125) 
Years left in term = 2   0.063   0.032   0.053 
  (0.100)   (0.077)   (0.122) 
Years left in term = 3   0.046   0.059   0.018 
  (0.105)   (0.069)   (0.120) 
Greens in government −0.135 −0.130 0.050 0.051 −0.196*** −0.193*** 
(0.080) (0.082) (0.095) (0.096) (0.064) (0.064) 
Green seats −0.008 −0.007 −0.005 −0.004 −0.009 −0.009 
(0.021) (0.021) (0.010) (0.010) (0.020) (0.020) 
Majority government 0.001 0.000 −0.028 −0.029 −0.005 −0.005 
(0.098) (0.099) (0.061) (0.061) (0.091) (0.091) 
Political constraints 0.351 0.341 −0.247 −0.257 0.326 0.322 
(0.426) (0.424) (0.275) (0.279) (0.432) (0.432) 
Domestic stocka 0.010** 0.010** −0.001 −0.001 0.014*** 0.014*** 
(0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) 
Domestic stock2,a −0.000** −0.000** 0.000** 0.000** −0.000*** −0.000*** 
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) 
GDP growth 0.009 0.009 0.006 0.006 0.006 0.006 
(0.009) (0.009) (0.004) (0.004) (0.011) (0.011) 
GDP p.c. (log) 0.100 0.103 −0.007 −0.004 0.107 0.107 
(0.080) (0.078) (0.034) (0.033) (0.073) (0.071) 
IEA member 0.120 0.121 0.117* 0.117* 0.054 0.055 
(0.146) (0.146) (0.059) (0.060) (0.159) (0.159) 
COP host 0.196 0.188 0.028 0.021 0.223 0.220 
(0.139) (0.143) (0.078) (0.077) (0.150) (0.153) 
Kyoto ratification −0.156 −0.151 0.091 0.092 −0.265* −0.262* 
(0.182) (0.182) (0.080) (0.081) (0.150) (0.151) 
EU member −0.066 −0.066 −0.058 −0.058 −0.028 −0.029 
(0.184) (0.184) (0.097) (0.097) (0.186) (0.186) 
Diffusion (neighbors) −0.000 −0.000 0.002* 0.002* −0.001 −0.001 
(0.002) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) 
Observations 768 768 768 768 768 768 
Log likelihood −618.545 −618.190 −343.896 −343.121 −626.950 −626.706 
R2 0.469 0.469 0.231 0.233 0.453 0.454 

All models include country and year fixed effects. Standard errors are in parentheses and clustered by country.

a

Estimates are for stocks of all climate policies in models 1, 2, 5, and 6 and stocks of soft policies in models 3 and 4.

*p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01.

Regression Findings

First, model 1 shows evidence that left governments are associated with more climate policy activity. The coefficient of the left government dummy variable is positive, as expected, and significant at the 5-percent level, thus supporting the first hypothesis. More precisely, controlling for the effect of the electoral cycle and all other variables in the model, the number of new policies increases by approximately 21 percent under a left government if compared to a center or right government. Second, judging by the associated nonsignificant coefficient, the electoral calendar does not appear to matter for climate policy production, thus rejecting the second hypothesis. This conclusion also holds when the electoral effect is estimated in terms of separate coefficients for the remaining years in the electoral term, treating four years left as the reference category (model 2). Models 3/4 and 5/6 show results split between hard and soft climate policies. The results do not support the existence of an electoral climate policy cycle conditional on the distinction between hard and soft policies (thus rejecting hypothesis 3). Rather, in line with the general literature on electoral cycles (De Haan and Klomp 2013; Dubois 2016), this suggests that the effect may be more complex and possibly conditional on other variables, such as partisan preferences. Comparing the effect of left government across the models indicates that the partisan effect is indeed conditional on policy type, as expected. The coefficients are highly significant for hard policies and insignificant for soft policies, suggesting that left governments produce more hard climate policies than center and right governments, but not more soft policies (thus supporting hypothesis 4).

Regarding the control variables, rather surprisingly, the results suggest that green representation in government has no effect on hard policies and is actually associated with fewer soft policies. However, the negative effect is not particularly robust and disappears, for instance, in models without fixed effects or if excluding years before 1999, which is when the IEA started to collect policy data (see the appendix, here: https://doi.org/10.1162/glep_a_00593).9 The results also suggest that previous experience with climate policy production has a positive effect on the introduction of additional soft policies and that this effect levels off at some point. The situation appears to be different for hard policies, where domestic stocks of soft policies only seem to exert a positive effect at higher levels.

To further test hypothesis 4, I next introduce interaction terms between government partisanship and the election cycle. Table 4 presents the results. As hypothesized, the results show that left governments are associated with the production of more hard climate policies but are unrelated to the production of soft policies as the election approaches. In model 3, the coefficient of the interaction term is negative and significant as expected, while the coefficient is insignificant in model 5. Precisely, according to model 3 and holding all other variables at their means, the number of hard climate policies increases by approximately 30 percent in the pre-election year under left government or by almost 160 percent compared with a center or right government in the same year.

Table 4

Climate Policy Production in Twenty-Nine IEA Member States, 1990–2016, Interaction Effects

 All PoliciesHard PoliciesSoft Policies
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Left government 0.247** 0.210 0.341*** 0.010 0.072 0.287 
(0.106) (0.230) (0.077) (0.087) (0.107) (0.243) 
Years left in term −0.008   0.038**   −0.033   
(0.024)   (0.014)   (0.024)   
Left × Years Left in Term −0.032   −0.076**   0.009   
(0.046)   (0.034)   (0.047)   
Years left in term = 0   0.051   −0.067   0.117 
  (0.115)   (0.065)   (0.129) 
Left × Years Left in Term = 0   0.102   0.233   −0.074 
  (0.268)   (0.155)   (0.278) 
Years left in term = 1   0.124   −0.112   0.212 
  (0.125)   (0.067)   (0.138) 
Left × Years Left in Term = 1   −0.052   0.411***   −0.360 
  (0.244)   (0.119)   (0.246) 
Years left in term = 2   0.090   0.004   0.116 
  (0.115)   (0.065)   (0.129) 
Left × Years Left in Term = 2   −0.079   0.154   −0.250 
  (0.247)   (0.108)   (0.270) 
Years left in term = 3   0.060   0.057   0.052 
  (0.111)   (0.076)   (0.121) 
Left × Years Left in Term = 3   −0.042   0.072   −0.162 
  (0.260)   (0.106)   (0.250) 
Observations 768 768 768 768 768 768 
Log likelihood −618.187 −617.110 −339.755 −334.231 −626.925 −623.607 
R2 0.469 0.470 0.240 0.250 0.453 0.458 
 All PoliciesHard PoliciesSoft Policies
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Left government 0.247** 0.210 0.341*** 0.010 0.072 0.287 
(0.106) (0.230) (0.077) (0.087) (0.107) (0.243) 
Years left in term −0.008   0.038**   −0.033   
(0.024)   (0.014)   (0.024)   
Left × Years Left in Term −0.032   −0.076**   0.009   
(0.046)   (0.034)   (0.047)   
Years left in term = 0   0.051   −0.067   0.117 
  (0.115)   (0.065)   (0.129) 
Left × Years Left in Term = 0   0.102   0.233   −0.074 
  (0.268)   (0.155)   (0.278) 
Years left in term = 1   0.124   −0.112   0.212 
  (0.125)   (0.067)   (0.138) 
Left × Years Left in Term = 1   −0.052   0.411***   −0.360 
  (0.244)   (0.119)   (0.246) 
Years left in term = 2   0.090   0.004   0.116 
  (0.115)   (0.065)   (0.129) 
Left × Years Left in Term = 2   −0.079   0.154   −0.250 
  (0.247)   (0.108)   (0.270) 
Years left in term = 3   0.060   0.057   0.052 
  (0.111)   (0.076)   (0.121) 
Left × Years Left in Term = 3   −0.042   0.072   −0.162 
  (0.260)   (0.106)   (0.250) 
Observations 768 768 768 768 768 768 
Log likelihood −618.187 −617.110 −339.755 −334.231 −626.925 −623.607 
R2 0.469 0.470 0.240 0.250 0.453 0.458 

All models include country and year fixed effects and the full set of controls from Table 3. Standard errors are in parentheses and clustered by country.

*p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01.

Inspecting the p-values of the interaction term can already be termed a rather conservative strategy in testing for the presence or absence of an interaction effect (Pepinsky 2018). However, the presence of an interaction effect still assumes sufficient common support across values of the moderator and linearity. I investigate both issues by employing the binning estimator routine developed by Hainmueller et al. (2019). The results are presented in Figure 3.

Figure 3

Marginal Effect Plot and Binning Estimator Based on Models 3 and 5 from Table 4. 

Figure 3

Marginal Effect Plot and Binning Estimator Based on Models 3 and 5 from Table 4. 

Close modal

The left panel shows the interaction effect for hard policies (model 3) and the right panel for soft policies (model 5). Little surprising, the distribution of observations and treatments over the electoral term is quite balanced, as indicated by the histograms at the bottom. There is one exception, however: there are fewer observations for four years left in the current term given that few countries in the sample maintain five-year election periods. In fact, the treatment effect is not identified in this case. Nevertheless, the left plot is quite consistent with the presence of an interactive effect between left government and the electoral cycle in the case of hard policies as, with the exception of three years left into the electoral term, neither the bins nor the marginal effect estimates cross zero. Moreover, there is only a limited overlap between the bin for one year and the bins for two and three years left in the term. By contrast, the right plot shows marginal effect estimates that slightly increase with more years left in the current term. However, the confidence intervals of both the marginal effects plot and the binning estimator cross zero and therefore confirm that there is no interactive relationship in the case of soft climate policy production.

Regarding linearity, the left panel shows that there might indeed be a problem, mainly related to the estimates for zero and one year left in the term.10 The Wald test also marginally rejects linearity, with a p-value of 0.08. In fact, with only a few unique values on the moderator variable, Hainmueller et al. (2019, 166) recommend estimating a fully saturated model using dummy variables and including all interaction terms. I follow this advice in models 2, 4, and 6 shown in Table 4. The results confirm that the production of hard policies increases in the pre-election year under left government (model 4), while all other interaction terms fail to achieve conventional levels of statistical significance. Overall, these results are therefore robustly in line with the fourth hypothesis and indicate that left governments are more likely to introduce hard climate policies before elections. Not only do left governments seem to be more willing to take the electoral risk of imposing more visible costs upon voters but, unlike center and right governments, they may actually perceive such policies as an opportunity to win or keep votes.

The new global climate governance architecture relies fundamentally on national climate policy making. In this context, this study sought to improve our understanding of the drivers of national policy efforts. In particular, I looked at the role that electoral competition plays in climate policy making, a relationship that can be deemed remarkably puzzling in previous research results. Addressing this puzzle, I expected that electoral incentives in climate policy making would be conditional on government ideology and policy characteristics. To show this, I compiled information on policy characteristics and merged them with data on government partisanship and electoral terms. This is a novel contribution to the climate policy and politics literature, especially to the existing large-n studies.

In general, the results show that soft climate policies, such as subsidies and information campaigns, are introduced in greater numbers than hard policies like taxes and standards under all types of partisan government and at all times during the electoral term. Contrary to what the existing literature suggests, the data show that overall, climate policy making in democracies tends to increase as elections get closer. This is due to increases in soft but not hard policies, the latter showing more stable production rates over the electoral term. Furthermore, the results suggest that electoral climate policy cycles vary depending on government ideology, with left governments being more inclined to pursue hard climate policies in the run-up to elections. Overall, these results paint a more nuanced and more optimistic picture of the effects of electoral competition on climate policy outputs than do the results of previous research. They suggest that the timing, nature, and partisan origins of climate policies deserve further attention from both climate politics scholars and climate policy advocates.

Of course, this contribution remains limited in several ways. First, as already mentioned, the data set does not allow for precisely identifying, for election years, which policies were introduced before and after the election date. Thus, more fine-grained time series data on policy introduction as well as partisan (and other) variables may be useful to verify the present initial findings. Second, while this aggregate analysis argues that conflict potential varies for different types of climate policies, it neither derives the conflict potential related to a given policy’s intensity (for instance, the level of a given tax or subsidy) nor does it relate to the expected outcomes of a given policy or policy type (see Peñasco et al. 2021). Future research may consider such details to further understand the nature and conditions of electoral incentives in climate policy making. Finally, future research should further establish what happens to the electoral fortunes of parties after the introduction of climate policies. In other words, studies of partisan differences in climate policy making should be complemented by efforts to determine whether climate policy making actually leads to electoral gains or losses (see, e.g., Stokes 2016).

1. 

Costs may even be passed on to future generations via deficit spending.

2. 

By pursuing direct investments and subsidies, policy makers may in fact seek credit for both economic stimuli, especially for green industries, and climate protection. These two motivations are not mutually exclusive. However, differing partisan and electoral incentives can still be expected, because policy makers can decide, based on their preferences, toward which industries and sectors (not) to target their stimulus policies.

3. 

Mexico joined the IEA in 2018 as the organization’s thirtieth member.

4. 

Monitoring and reporting mechanisms can be important “hard” components even of governance frameworks that are soft in principle (Knodt and Schoenefeld 2020).

5. 

Feed-in tariffs (FIT) are distinguished further between more-visible-cost systems paid through user charges and less-visible-cost systems paid through the general budget. Data collection also involved extensive desk research for policies in the IEA database that had unclear or missing information.

6. 

Despite important advances (Howlett and Cashore 2009; Knill et al. 2012; Schaffrin et al. 2015; Schmidt and Sewerin 2019), the measurement of policy intensity remains particularly challenging, especially in aggregate analyses facing complex policy mixes. Open questions include, for example, how to measure, aggregate, and relate different policy components to one another; how to consider different contexts; and finally, how this influences policy processes and the behavior of policy makers (for a recent discussion, see Capano and Howlett 2020).

7. 

This is a reasonable simplification, as no governments are dominated by the left and only a few are dominated by the right in the data set. I extended the Seki–Williams data to 2016 and added data for South Korea. Data on electoral terms come from the Database of Political Institutions (DPI) (Cruz et al. 2018).

8. 

The appendix (https://doi.org/10.1162/glep_a_00593) to this article includes summary statistics and data sources for all variables as well as a battery of robustness checks, which all confirm the main conclusions. For instance, I use the share of hard and soft policy production instead of counts, add center and right governments to the models, and measure government ideology in terms of the cabinet seat shares and in terms of left–right and environmental policy positions derived from manifesto data. I also add further control variables, estimate negative binomial regression models without fixed effects, and drop each country in turn to see whether results are driven by particular countries.

9. 

The data also show that governments with green parties actually produce both more hard and more soft policies on average than left, center, and right governments without green party representation. I therefore recommend that these results not be overstated. Convincing explanations of this result and the absence of a green party effect would likely require further in-depth study of those government coalitions with green party participation.

10. 

As already mentioned, the estimates for the election year should generally be treated with caution given the lack of precision with which both partisan government and policy production are measured here.

Adams
,
James
, and
Zeynep
Somer-Topcu
.
2009
.
Do Parties Adjust Their Policies in Response to Rival Parties’ Policy Shifts? Spatial Theory and the Dynamics of Party Competition in Twenty-Five Postwar Democracies
.
British Journal of Political Science
39
(
4
):
825
846
.
Aklin
,
Michaël
, and
Johannes
Urpelainen
.
2013
.
Political Competition, Path Dependence, and the Strategy of Sustainable Energy Transitions
.
American Journal of Political Science
57
(
3
):
643
658
.
Allison
,
Paul D.
, and
Richard P.
Waterman
.
2002
.
Fixed-Effects Negative Binomial Regression Models
.
Sociological Methodology
32
(
1
):
247
265
.
Avrami
,
Lydia
, and
Detlef F.
Sprinz
.
2019
.
Measuring and Explaining the EU’s Effect on National Climate Performance
.
Environmental Politics
28
(
5
):
822
846
.
Bäck
,
Hanna
,
Marc
Debus
, and
Jale
Tosun
.
2015
.
Partisanship, Ministers, and Biotechnology Policy
.
Review of Policy Research
32
(
5
):
556
575
.
Båtstrand
,
Sondre
.
2014
.
Giving Content to New Politics: From Broad Hypothesis to Empirical Analysis Using Norwegian Manifesto Data on Climate Change
.
Party Politics
20
(
6
):
930
939
.
Bättig
,
Michèle B.
,
Simone
Brander
, and
Dieter M.
Imboden
.
2008
.
Measuring Countries’ Cooperation Within the International Climate Change Regime
.
Environmental Science & Policy
11
(
6
):
478
489
.
Bayer
,
Patrick
, and
Johannes
Urpelainen
.
2016
.
It Is All About Political Incentives: Democracy and the Renewable Feed-in Tariff
.
Journal of Politics
78
(
2
):
603
619
.
Bernauer
,
Thomas
.
2013
.
Climate Change Politics
.
Annual Review of Political Science
16
(
1
):
421
448
.
Bernhagen
,
Patrick
.
2008
.
Business and International Environmental Agreements: Domestic Sources of Participation and Compliance by Advanced Industrialized Democracies
.
Global Environmental Politics
8
(
1
):
78
110
.
Berry
,
Michael J.
,
Frank N.
Laird
, and
Christoph H.
Stefes
.
2015
.
Driving Energy: The Enactment and Ambitiousness of State Renewable Energy Policy
.
Journal of Public Policy
35
(
2
):
297
328
.
Besley
,
Timothy
, and
Anne
Case
.
1995
.
Does Electoral Accountability Affect Economic Policy Choices? Evidence from Gubernatorial Term Limits
.
Quarterly Journal of Economics
110
(
3
):
769
798
.
Böhmelt
,
Tobias
,
Marit
Böker
, and
Hugh
Ward
.
2016
.
Democratic Inclusiveness, Climate Policy Outputs, and Climate Policy Outcomes
.
Democratization
23
(
7
):
1272
1291
.
Bove
,
Vincenzo
, and
Tobias
Böhmelt
.
2016
.
Does Immigration Induce Terrorism?
Journal of Politics
78
(
2
):
572
588
.
Breetz
,
Hanna
,
Matto
Mildenberger
, and
Leah
Stokes
.
2018
.
The Political Logics of Clean Energy Transitions
.
Business and Politics
20
(
4
):
492
522
.
Cao
,
Xun
,
Helen V.
Milner
,
Aseem
Prakash
, and
Hugh
Ward
.
2014
.
Research Frontiers in Comparative and International Environmental Politics: An Introduction
.
Comparative Political Studies
47
(
3
):
291
308
.
Cao
,
Xun
, and
Hugh
Ward
.
2016
.
Transnational Climate Governance Networks and Domestic Regulatory Action
.
International Interactions
43
(
1
):
76
102
.
Capano
,
Giliberto
, and
Michael
Howlett
.
2020
.
The Knowns and Unknowns of Policy Instrument Analysis: Policy Tools and the Current Research Agenda on Policy Mixes
.
SAGE Open
10
(
1
):
1
13
.
Capstick
,
Stuart
,
Lorraine
Whitmarsh
,
Wouter
Poortinga
,
Nick
Pidgeon
, and
Paul
Upham
.
2015
.
International Trends in Public Perceptions of Climate Change over the Past Quarter Century
.
Wiley Interdisciplinary Reviews: Climate Change
6
(
1
):
35
61
.
Carter
,
Neil
.
2013
.
Greening the Mainstream: Party Politics and the Environment
.
Environmental Politics
22
(
1
):
73
94
.
Carter
,
Neil
,
Robert
Ladrech
,
Conor
Little
, and
Vasiliki
Tsagkroni
.
2018
.
Political Parties and Climate Policy
.
Party Politics
24
(
6
):
731
742
.
Cazals
,
Antoine
, and
Alexandre
Sauquet
.
2015
.
How Do Elections Affect International Cooperation? Evidence from Environmental Treaty Participation
.
Public Choice
162
(
3–4
):
263
285
.
Cheon
,
Andrew
, and
Johannes
Urpelainen
.
2013
.
How Do Competing Interest Groups Influence Environmental Policy? The Case of Renewable Electricity in Industrialized Democracies, 1989–2007
.
Political Studies
61
(
4
):
874
897
.
Cruz
,
Cesi
,
Philip
Keefer
, and
Carlos
Scartascini
.
2018
.
Database of Political Institutions 2017 (DPI2017)
.
Washington, DC
:
Inter-American Development Bank
.
Dalton
,
Russell J.
2009
.
Economics, Environmentalism and Party Alignments: A Note on Partisan Change in Advanced Industrial Democracies
.
European Journal of Political Research
48
(
2
):
161
175
.
De Haan
,
Jakob
, and
Jeroen
Klomp
.
2013
.
Conditional Political Budget Cycles: A Review of Recent Evidence
.
Public Choice
157
(
3
):
387
410
.
Dolšak
,
Nives
.
2001
.
Mitigating Global Climate Change: Why Are Some Countries More Committed than Others?
Policy Studies Journal
29
(
3
):
414
436
.
Dubash
,
Navroz K.
,
Markus
Hagemann
,
Niklas
Höhne
, and
Prabhat
Upadhyaya
.
2013
.
Developments in National Climate Change Mitigation Legislation and Strategy
.
Climate Policy
13
(
6
):
649
664
.
Dubois
,
Eric
.
2016
.
Political Business Cycles 40 Years After Nordhaus
.
Public Choice
166
(
1
):
235
259
.
Dunlap
,
Riley E.
,
Aaron M.
McCright
, and
Jerrod H.
Yarosh
.
2016
.
The Political Divide on Climate Change: Partisan Polarization Widens in the US
.
Environment: Science and Policy for Sustainable Development
58
(
5
):
4
23
.
Dupuis
,
Johann
, and
Robbert
Biesbroek
.
2013
.
Comparing Apples and Oranges: The Dependent Variable Problem in Comparing and Evaluating Climate Change Adaptation Policies
.
Global Environmental Change
23
(
6
):
1476
1487
.
Facchini
,
Francois
,
Guiseppe Lucio
Gaeta
, and
Benjamin
Michallet
.
2017
.
Who Cares About the Environment? An Empirical Analysis of the Evolution of Political Parties’ Environmental Concern in European Countries (1970–2008)
.
Land Use Policy
64
:
200
211
.
Fagerholm
,
Andreas
.
2016
.
Social Democratic Parties and the Rise of Ecologism: A Comparative Analysis of Western Europe
.
Comparative European Politics
14
(
5
):
547
571
.
Fankhauser
,
Sam
,
Caterina
Gennaioli
, and
Murray
Collins
.
2015a
.
The Political Economy of Passing Climate Change Legislation: Evidence from a Survey
.
Global Environmental Change
35
:
52
61
.
Fankhauser
,
Samuel
,
Caterina
Gennaioli
, and
Murray
Collins
.
2015b
.
Do International Factors Influence the Passage of Climate Change Legislation?
Climate Policy
16
(
3
):
318
331
.
Farstad
,
Fay M.
2018
.
What Explains Variation in Parties’ Climate Change Salience?
Party Politics
24
(
6
):
698
707
.
Franzese
,
Robert J.
, Jr.
2002
.
Electoral and Partisan Cycles in Economic Policies and Outcomes
.
Annual Review of Political Science
5
(
1
):
369
421
.
Fredriksson
,
Per G.
,
Herman R. J.
Vollebergh
, and
Elbert
Dijkgraaf
.
2004
.
Corruption and Energy Efficiency in OECD Countries: Theory and Evidence
.
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management
47
(
2
):
207
231
.
Garmann
,
Sebastian
.
2014
.
Do Government Ideology and Fragmentation Matter for Reducing CO2-Emissions? Empirical Evidence from OECD Countries
.
Ecological Economics
105
:
1
10
.
Gleditsch
,
Kristian Skrede
, and
Sara M. T.
Polo
.
2016
.
Ethnic Inclusion, Democracy, and Terrorism
.
Public Choice
169
(
3
):
207
229
.
Hainmueller
,
Jens
,
Jonathan
Mummolo
, and
Yiqing
Xu
.
2019
.
How Much Should We Trust Estimates from Multiplicative Interaction Models? Simple Tools to Improve Empirical Practice
.
Political Analysis
27
(
2
):
163
192
.
Hakelberg
,
Lukas
.
2014
.
Governance by Diffusion: Transnational Municipal Networks and the Spread of Local Climate Strategies in Europe
.
Global Environmental Politics
14
(
1
):
107
129
.
Harrison
,
Kathryn
, and
Lisa
McIntosh Sundstrom
.
2007
.
The Comparative Politics of Climate Change
.
Global Environmental Politics
7
(
4
):
1
18
.
Henisz
,
Witold J.
2000
.
The Institutional Environment for Economic Growth
.
Economics and Politics
12
(
1
):
1
31
.
Hibbs
,
Douglas A.
1977
.
Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy
.
American Political Science Review
71
(
4
):
1467
1487
.
Hildén
,
Mikael
.
2011
.
The Evolution of Climate Policies: The Role of Learning and Evaluations
.
Journal of Cleaner Production
19
(
16
):
1798
1811
.
Hornsey
,
Matthew J.
,
Emily A.
Harris
,
Paul G.
Bain
, and
Kelly S.
Fielding
.
2016
.
Meta-analyses of the Determinants and Outcomes of Belief in Climate Change
.
Nature Climate Change
6
(
6
):
622
626
.
Howlett
,
Michael
, and
Benjamin
Cashore
.
2009
.
The Dependent Variable Problem in the Study of Policy Change: Understanding Policy Change as a Methodological Problem
.
Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and Practice
11
(
1
):
33
46
.
Hughes
,
Llewelyn
, and
Johannes
Urpelainen
.
2015
.
Interests, Institutions, and Climate Policy: Explaining the Choice of Policy Instruments for the Energy Sector
.
Environmental Science & Policy
54
:
52
63
.
International Energy Agency
.
2020
.
Policies and Measures Database
.
Paris, France
:
International Energy Agency
.
Jacobs
,
Alan M.
2016
.
Policy Making for the Long Term in Advanced Democracies
.
Annual Review of Political Science
19
(
1
):
433
454
.
Jahn
,
Detlef
.
2016
.
The Politics of Environmental Performance: Institutions and Preferences in Industrialized Democracies
.
Cambridge, UK
:
Cambridge University Press
.
Jahn
,
Detlef
, and
Sebastian
Korolczuk
.
2012
.
German Exceptionalism: The End of Nuclear Energy in Germany!
Environmental Politics
21
(
1
):
159
164
.
Jensen
,
Christian B.
, and
Jae-Jae
Spoon
.
2011
.
Testing the “Party Matters” Thesis: Explaining Progress Towards Kyoto Protocol Targets
.
Political Studies
59
(
1
):
99
115
.
Jordan
,
Andrew
,
Rüdiger K.W.
Wurzel
, and
Anthony R.
Zito
.
2013
.
Still the Century of ‘New’ Environmental Policy Instruments? Exploring Patterns of Innovation and Continuity
.
Environmental Politics
22
(
1
):
155
173
.
Jordan
,
Andrew
, and
Dave
Huitema
.
2014
.
Innovations in Climate Policy: The Politics of Invention, Diffusion, and Evaluation
.
Environmental Politics
23
(
5
):
715
734
.
Jordan
,
Andrew
,
Dave
Huitema
,
Harro
van Asselt
, and
Johanna
Forster
, editors.
2018
.
Governing Climate Change: Polycentricity in Action?
Cambridge, UK
:
Cambridge University Press
.
Keohane
,
Robert O.
2015
.
The Global Politics of Climate Change: Challenge for Political Science
.
PS: Political Science & Politics
48
(
1
):
19
26
.
King
,
Ronald Frederick
, and
Alexandra
Borchardt
.
1994
.
Red and Green: Air Pollution Levels and Left Party Power in OECD Countries
.
Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy
12
(
2
):
225
241
.
Kitschelt
,
Herbert
.
1994
.
The Transformation of European Social Democracy
.
Cambridge, UK
:
Cambridge University Press
.
Knill
,
Christoph
,
Kai
Schulze
, and
Jale
Tosun
.
2012
.
Regulatory Policy Outputs and Impacts: Exploring a Complex Relationship
.
Regulation & Governance
5
(
4
):
427
444
.
Knodt
,
Michèle
, and
Jonas J.
Schoenefeld
.
2020
.
Harder Soft Governance in European Climate and Energy Policy: Exploring a New Trend in Public Policy
.
Journal of Environmental Policy & Planning
22
(
6
):
1
13
.
Lachapelle
,
Erick
, and
Matthew
Paterson
.
2013
.
Drivers of National Climate Policy
.
Climate Policy
13
(
5
):
547
571
.
Ladrech
,
Robert
, and
Conor
Little
.
2019
.
Drivers of Political Parties’ Climate Policy Preferences: Lessons from Denmark and Ireland
.
Environmental Politics
28
(
6
):
1017
1038
.
Le Quéré
,
Corinne
,
Jan Ivar
Korsbakken
,
Charlie
Wilson
,
Jale
Tosun
,
Robbie
Andrew
,
Robert J.
Andres
,
Josep G.
Canadell
,
Andrew
Jordan
,
Glen P.
Peters
, and
Detlef P.
van Vuuren
.
2019
.
Drivers of Declining CO2 Emissions in 18 Developed Economies
.
Nature Climate Change
9
(
3
):
213
217
.
List
,
John A.
, and
Daniel M.
Sturm
.
2006
.
How Elections Matter: Theory and Evidence from Environmental Policy
.
Quarterly Journal of Economics
121
(
4
):
1249
1281
.
Madden
,
Nathan J.
2014
.
Greenmeans Stop: Veto Players and Their Impact on Climate-Change Policy Outputs
.
Environmental Politics
23
(
4
):
570
589
.
Makse
,
Todd
, and
Craig
Volden
.
2011
.
The Role of Policy Attributes in the Diffusion of Innovations
.
Journal of Politics
73
(
1
):
108
124
.
Matisoff
,
Daniel C.
2008
.
The Adoption of State Climate Change Policies and Renewable Portfolio Standards: Regional Diffusion or Internal Determinants?
Review of Policy Research
25
(
6
):
527
546
.
Matisoff
,
Daniel C.
, and
Jason
Edwards
.
2014
.
Kindred Spirits or Intergovernmental Competition? The Innovation and Diffusion of Energy Policies in the American States (1990–2008)
.
Environmental Politics
25
(
5
):
795
817
.
McAlexander
,
Richard J.
, and
Johannes
Urpelainen
.
2020
.
Elections and Policy Responsiveness: Evidence from Environmental Voting in the US Congress
.
Review of Policy Research
37
(
1
):
39
63
.
McCright
,
Aaron M.
,
Riley E.
Dunlap
, and
Sandra T.
Marquart-Pyatt
.
2015
.
Political Ideology and Views About Climate Change in the European Union
.
Environmental Politics
25
(
2
):
338
358
.
Meckling
,
Jonas
, and
Jonas
Nahm
.
2018
.
The Power of Process: State Capacity and Climate Policy
.
Governance
31
(
4
):
741
757
.
Neumayer
,
Eric
.
2003
.
Are Left Party Strength and Corporatism Good for the Environment? Evidence from a Panel Analysis of Air Pollution in OECD Countries
.
Ecological Economics
45
(
2
):
203
220
.
Neumayer
,
Eric
.
2004
.
The Environment, Left-Wing Political Orientation and Ecological Economics
.
Ecological Economics
51
(
3–4
):
167
175
.
Nordhaus
,
William D.
1975
.
The Political Business Cycle
.
Review of Economic Studies
42
(
2
):
169
190
.
Pahle
,
Michael
,
Dallas
Burtraw
,
Christian
Flachsland
,
Nina
Kelsey
,
Eric
Biber
,
Jonas
Meckling
,
Ottmar
Edenhofer
, and
John
Zysman
.
2018
.
Sequencing to Ratchet Up Climate Policy Stringency
.
Nature Climate Change
8
(
10
):
861
867
.
Peñasco
,
Cristina
,
Laura D.
Anadón
, and
Elena
Verdolini
.
2021
.
Systematic Review of the Outcomes and Trade-Offs of Ten Types of Decarbonization Policy Instruments
.
Nature Climate Change
:
1
9
.
Pepinsky
,
Thomas B.
2018
.
Visual Heuristics for Marginal Effects Plots
.
Research & Politics
5
(
1
):
205316801875666
.
Potrafke
,
Niklas
.
2017
.
Partisan Politics: The Empirical Evidence from OECD Panel Studies
.
Journal of Comparative Economics
45
(
4
):
712
750
.
Purdon
,
Mark
.
2015
.
Advancing Comparative Climate Change Politics: Theory and Method
.
Global Environmental Politics
15
(
3
):
1
26
.
Rockström
,
Johan
,
Owen
Gaffney
,
Joeri
Rogelj
,
Malte
Meinshausen
,
Nebojsa
Nakicenovic
, and
Hans Joachim
Schellnhuber
.
2017
.
A Roadmap for Rapid Decarbonization
.
Science
355
(
6331
):
1269
1271
.
Sager
,
Fritz
.
2009
.
Governance and Coercion
.
Political Studies
57
(
3
):
537
558
.
Schaffer
,
Lena Maria
, and
Thomas
Bernauer
.
2014
.
Explaining Government Choices for Promoting Renewable Energy
.
Energy Policy
68
:
15
27
.
Schaffrin
,
André
,
Sebastian
Sewerin
, and
Sibylle
Seubert
.
2015
.
Toward a Comparative Measure of Climate Policy Output
.
Policy Studies Journal
43
(
2
):
257
282
.
Schmidt
,
Tobias S.
, and
Sebastian
Sewerin
.
2019
.
Measuring the Temporal Dynamics of Policy Mixes – An Empirical Analysis of Renewable Energy Policy Mixes’ Balance and Design Features in Nine Countries
.
Research Policy
48
(
10
):
103557
.
Schoenefeld
,
Jonas J.
,
Kai
Schulze
,
Mikael
Hildén
, and
Andrew J.
Jordan
.
2019
.
Policy Monitoring in the EU: The Impact of Institutions, Implementation, and Quality
.
Politische Vierteljahresschrift
60
(
4
):
719
741
.
Schreurs
,
Miranda A.
, and
Yves
Tiberghien
.
2007
.
Multi-level Reinforcement: Explaining European Union Leadership in Climate Change Mitigation
.
Global Environmental Politics
7
(
4
):
19
46
.
Schulze
,
Kai
.
2014
.
Do Parties Matter for International Environmental Cooperation? An Analysis of Environmental Treaty Participation by Advanced Industrialised Democracies
.
Environmental Politics
23
(
1
):
115
139
.
Seki
,
Katsunori
, and
Laron K.
Williams
.
2014
.
Updating the Party Government Data Set
.
Electoral Studies
34
:
270
279
.
Shwom
,
Rachael
,
David
Bidwell
,
Amy
Dan
, and
Thomas
Dietz
.
2010
.
Understanding US Public Support for Domestic Climate Change Policies
.
Global Environmental Change
20
(
3
):
472
482
.
Spoon
,
Jae-Jae
,
Sara B.
Hobolt
, and
Catherine E.
de Vries
.
2014
.
Going Green: Explaining Issue Competition on the Environment
.
European Journal of Political Research
53
(
2
):
363
380
.
Steurer
,
Reinhard
.
2011
.
Soft Instruments, Few Networks: How ‘New Governance’ Materializes in Public Policies on Corporate Social Responsibility Across Europe
.
Environmental Policy and Governance
21
(
4
):
270
290
.
Stokes
,
Leah C.
2016
.
Electoral Backlash Against Climate Policy: A Natural Experiment on Retrospective Voting and Local Resistance to Public Policy
.
American Journal of Political Science
60
(
4
):
958
974
.
Tews
,
Kerstin
,
Per-Olof
Busch
, and
Helge
Jörgens
.
2003
.
The Diffusion of New Environmental Policy Instruments
.
European Journal of Political Research
42
(
4
):
569
600
.
Tobin
,
Paul
.
2017
.
Leaders and Laggards: Climate Policy Ambition in Developed States
.
Global Environmental Politics
17
(
4
):
28
47
.
Vedung
,
Evert
.
1998
.
Policy Instruments: Typologies and Theories
. In
Carrots, Sticks, and Sermons: Policy Instruments and Their Evaluation
, edited by
M. L.
Bemelmans-Videc
,
Ray C.
Rist
, and
Evert
Vedung
,
21
58
.
New Brunswick, NJ
:
Transaction
.
Ward
,
Hugh
, and
Xun
Cao
.
2012
.
Domestic and International Influences on Green Taxation
.
Comparative Political Studies
45
(
9
):
1075
1103
.
Wehner
,
Joachim
.
2013
.
Electoral Budget Cycles in Legislatures
.
Legislative Studies Quarterly
38
(
4
):
545
570
.
Woldendorp
,
Jaap
,
Hans
Keman
, and
Ian
Budge
.
2000
.
Party Government in 48 Democracies (1945–1998): Composition, Duration, Personnel
.
Dordrecht, Netherlands
:
Kluwer Academic
.

Author notes

*

I am grateful to Heike Böhler for her valuable comments and support collecting some of the empirical data for this article. Earlier versions of this article were presented at the APSA annual meeting (2020), the Annual Conference of Environmental Politics and Governance (2020), the ECPR General Conference (2017), and the INOGOV Workshop on Climate Governance Innovation (2017). I thank the discussants and participants of these events, in particular, Alexander Gard-Murray, Detlef Jahn, Jonas Schmid, Liam Beiser-McGrath, and Michael Tomz. I also thank Jonas Schönefeld as well as three anonymous reviewers and the editors of this journal for their valuable comments and constructive suggestions.

This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. For a full description of the license, please visit https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/legalcode.

Supplementary data