In 1991, in meetings constructing the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, the small island state of Vanuatu introduced a proposal requiring wealthy countries to pay for damages related to sea level rise. More than thirty years later, countries finally agreed to establish a financing mechanism for loss and damage associated with climate change. Scholars have observed the slow progress on loss and damage finance, but what tactics did countries use to obstruct negotiations? We answer this question using data from primary and secondary sources, observations at negotiations, and key informant interviews. Our analysis details four periods of obstruction and outlines a typology of fourteen tactics countries have used to delay progress. These tactics limited the issue’s scope, reduced transparency, manipulated language, and advanced nontransformative solutions. These findings contribute to the study of obstructionism in climate governance and can help loss and damage advocates better anticipate and respond to obstruction.

When asked at the 2015 climate negotiations in Paris whether the United States would pay for climate-related damages, lead US negotiator Todd Stern said bluntly, “We are in favor of support, technical and financial support, going to countries with loss and damage. … There’s one thing that we don’t accept … which is the notion that there should be liability and compensation for loss and damage. Virtually all developed countries [agree]” (quoted in Adler 2015, 9). Six years later, at the Glasgow Dialogue in 2021, where parties discussed funding arrangements for loss and damage, Global North countries like the United States doubled down on their opposition to establishing a dedicated fund to address the issue (Weise and Mathiesen 2021).

Tensions regarding loss and damage1 finance in the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) can be traced to the very beginning of the multilateral negotiations. In 1991, during the Intergovernmental Negotiating Committee (INC) meetings that drafted the foundational text for the convention, Vanuatu submitted a significant proposal on behalf of the Alliance of Small Island States (AOSIS) (Intergovernmental Negotiating Committee [INC] 1991). The proposal outlined an insurance mechanism that wealthy Global North countries would finance to protect against observed and future climate impacts, particularly sea level rise. Yet, countries excluded this proposal from the final text adopted the following year in Rio in 1992. Only Article 4 of the UNFCCC mentions “insurance” as one of several actions that parties “shall give full consideration to” (United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change [UNFCCC] 1992, 8). A financial mechanism was not formalized until 2022, when parties agreed at the twenty-seventh meeting of the Conference of the Parties to the UNFCCC (COP27) to set up a fund for loss and damage.

Over the more than thirty years between 1991 and 2022, Global South countries and civil society advocates have consistently and increasingly argued that Global North countries should fund losses and damages associated with climate change. These countries are disproportionately responsible for and are far more capable of addressing these impacts. Because finance is fundamental to vulnerable countries’ ability to manage climate impacts independently, opposition to loss and damage finance is “the ultimate manifestation of climate injustice” (Galvão Ferreira 2021, 127). The financial dimension of loss and damage made it more difficult to negotiate. Studies show that finance-related agenda items are more contentious (less “integrative”) than other issues (Odell 2013; Walton and McKersie 1965; Winham 1986). This reflects a broader pattern in global governance, whereby demands for compensation often result in contestation and inaction.

We use the case of loss and damage finance to explore obstructionism in the United Nations (UN) climate negotiations. Specifically, we ask, what tactics have countries used to obstruct loss and damage finance in the UNFCCC? Drawing on data from primary and secondary sources, such as submissions by parties, observations at UN negotiations, and interviews with twelve key informants, we trace the emergence and evolution of loss and damage finance in the UNFCCC from the early 1990s to the 2020s. Based on our analysis, we develop a typology of obstructionist tactics that countries have used to delay action on loss and damage over the last thirty years. We define obstruction as any intentional slowing or blocking of policy or action on loss and damage finance. This includes efforts to prevent the adoption of UNFCCC text that acknowledges loss and damage as a concern and specifies that countries should provide funds to address the issue. This conception builds on the normative stance that finance for loss and damage is an essential mechanism for climate justice, which vulnerable countries have advocated for decades. We interpret obstructionist tactics along a continuum of “hard” and “soft” bargaining to explain how countries kept loss and damage finance out of UNFCCC texts for three decades.

The article comprises four parts. First, we review international negotiation scholarship and use a hard–soft bargaining continuum to assess obstructionist tactics in the UNFCCC. Second, we provide a brief history of loss and damage in the UNFCCC, including how obstruction to financial obligations emerged and how it has evolved. The first period centers on the 1991 Vanuatu proposal and the lack of progress over the subsequent sixteen years. The second period covers the 2007 Bali Action Plan to the establishment of the Warsaw International Mechanism (WIM) for Loss and Damage in 2013. The third and fourth periods trace the 2013 WIM to the 2015 Paris Agreement and the Paris Agreement to the 2022 decision in Sharm el-Sheikh to establish a fund for loss and damage. We then present a typology of obstructionist tactics used by Global North countries that comprises four tactical categories: limiting the scope of the issue, reducing transparency, manipulating concepts, and pushing nontransformative solutions. This typology could help improve our understanding of negotiating tactics in other areas of environmental governance and global governance more generally. It could also help loss and damage advocates better anticipate and respond to climate obstructionism in the negotiations. We conclude by explaining how scholars and practitioners can use our typology to hold countries accountable for obstructionist positions. We anticipate that work to obstruct the flow of finance to loss and damage will continue, regardless of the recent decision to establish a funding mechanism. Identifying and countering obstructionist practices are crucial for delivering just climate action.

For decades, countries in the Global South, particularly small islands, have advocated for action on loss and damage (Adelman 2016; Calliari 2018; Mace and Verheyen 2016; Robinson and Carlson 2021). By contrast, countries in the Global North2 have historically opposed, first, a formal distinction between climate adaptation and loss and damage and, second, liability and compensation to address the issue (Burkett 2016; Linnerooth-Bayer et al. 2019; Page and Heyward 2017; Roberts and Huq 2015; Roberts and Parks 2007; Vanhala and Hestbaek 2016). The highly contentious nature of loss and damage in the UNFCCC (see Boyd et al. 2017; Calliari et al. 2020; McNamara and Jackson 2019; see also other articles in this issue) makes it an informative case for assessing obstructionist behavior in international negotiations.

Despite growing attention to climate obstruction at the domestic level around the world,3 obstruction at the international level is relatively underexplored (Green 2020). The most extensive thread of scholarship explores how private actors and coalitions thwart climate action (e.g., Ciplet et al. 2015; Levy and Egan 1998; Meckling 2011; Mildenberger 2020; Newell and Paterson 2010; Stokes 2020). A much smaller body of work explores the tactics countries use to impede progress at the international level. For example, Depledge (2008) traces Saudi Arabia’s efforts to obstruct mitigation policy in the UNFCCC. Although this case uncovers valuable insights about the specific tactics Saudi Arabia employs, this country represents an extreme case (Depledge 2008, 10). Our analysis builds on these initial studies by examining obstruction carried out in international negotiations by a range of actors over many years and identifies the specific tactics that they have used.

We define international negotiation as “a process in which actors take steps to agree on an outcome, and all the actors seek to make that outcome as good as possible from their own perspectives” (Odell and Tingley 2016, 231). All parties engage in UNFCCC negotiations to advance their interests. Although scholars have categorized negotiating behavior in many ways—value-claiming and value-creating strategies (Odell 2018), (convergent) bargaining and problem-solving bargaining strategies (Wagner 1999), and bargaining and arguing (Dür and Mateo 2010; Risse 2000)—we adopt a distinction between “hard” and “soft” bargaining (Bailer 2012; Dür and Mateo 2010; Weiler 2012). Relative to other classifications, this typology avoids some of the analytical challenges to studying international negotiations. Hard–soft approaches to bargaining are easier to observe empirically; they also omit assumptions about the intentionality underpinning strategies (Dür and Mateo 2010). On one end of the continuum, hard bargaining is an ideal type that encompasses “conflictual or aggressive tactics” that maximize the distribution of resources among some parties relative to others (Dür and Mateo 2010, 561). A hard bargaining tactic might include refusing to accept a priority of another party or misrepresenting one’s minimal needs. On the other end of the continuum, soft bargaining comprises “cooperative or friendly” negotiating tactics (Dür and Mateo 2010, 561). Soft bargaining tactics might include emphasizing the collective interests of an issue and advancing new or flexible proposals for compromise.

We use this hard–soft continuum to assess obstructionist behavior in international negotiations. Specifically, we trace how countries have used hard and soft tactics to obstruct loss and damage in the UNFCCC from the 1990s to the 2020s. By obstruction, we refer to the intentional slowing or blocking of policy or action on climate change that is commensurate with the current scientific consensus of what is necessary to avoid dangerous human-caused interference with the climate system (see Ekberg et al. 2023). Loss and damage finance obstruction is a negotiating strategy: a long-term guiding plan or objective. And the strategy is composed of negotiating tactics: individual actions and steps to get there.

In their initial elaboration of this hard–soft continuum in the context of European Union negotiations, Dür and Mateo (2010) found that parties with more “bargaining power,” directly related to material wealth, were more likely to employ hard bargaining tactics. In the UNFCCC, this would suggest that wealthy countries like the United States would be hard bargainers. In studies of the UNFCCC, some scholars have suggested that Global South countries have actually been those with a hard, uncompromising approach to negotiation, while Global North countries (apart from the United States) have worked to find constructive solutions (Gupta 2012). Others have argued that the structure of international negotiations can override parties’ material power in bargaining (McKibben 2013) and that cultural factors can influence whether a country will employ hard or soft bargaining tactics (Martill and Staiger 2021). The consensus-based bargaining structure of the UNFCCC may then lead parties to take whatever approach is necessary to get others to concede, given the need for a collective agreement. Weiler (2012) finds that the use of soft bargaining in climate negotiations can be more effective in negotiating success when they aim to benefit all concerned parties mutually.

We contribute to this small set of studies by elaborating on the use of hard and soft bargaining in the UNFCCC on an issue of particular importance to parties that are materially weak (Betzold 2010; Ciplet et al. 2015; Águeda Corneloup and Mol 2014; Rasheed 2019). The very fact that wealthy countries use obstructionist tactics suggests that power in international climate politics is more than a function of materiality.4 Though we do not trace hard–soft bargaining tactics among all actors in the UNFCCC around loss and damage finance, our case provides an opportunity to understand how these countries approach bargaining on such a key issue. Finance is ultimately a linchpin for loss and damage negotiations, but scholars have yet to examine the deliberate efforts to obstruct loss and damage finance over time. The analysis that follows addresses this gap.

To determine the tactics countries have used to obstruct loss and damage finance in the UNFCCC, we divide more than thirty years of negotiations into four periods based on significant texts that advanced the issue of loss and damage (Table 1) (for the history on which we base this periodization, see Falzon et al. 2022; see also Galvão Ferreira 2021; Siegele 2021a, 2021b; Vanhala and Hestbaek 2016). In each period, we identify the demands advanced by loss and damage advocates and the obstructionist tactics opponents used to thwart the realization of these demands (see Table 2). To construct this history, we triangulated data gathered from interviews with key informants, observations at UNFCCC meetings between 2013 and 2022, primary documents from the UNFCCC (e.g., country submissions, reports, decision texts), and secondary documentation of events from researchers, reporters, and advocacy groups, including the Climate Action Network and the Third World Network. We selected informants based on their close involvement in key loss and damage negotiations and related committees and groups (e.g., country negotiators, legal advisors, leading climate advocates, and academics from countries in the Global South and North). The interview protocol for each interviewee began with questions to elicit their perspective on the history of loss and damage finance in the negotiations, from the beginning of their involvement. We asked follow-up questions for details regarding specific events in the negotiations identified through our document analysis (e.g., the establishment of the WIM) and moments that they identified as significant. All informants were granted anonymity as the basis for their contribution to this study. As a result, the information presented herein is never attributed to specific individuals.

Table 1

Four Periods of Contention over Loss and Damage Finance in the UNFCCC and Positions Taken by Advocates and Opponents

PeriodYearsMilestonesL&D Finance AdvocatesL&D Finance Obstructionists
1991–2007 1991: AOSIS proposal 
  • Vanuatu/AOSIS worked to include L&D in the 1992 text of the UNFCCC Convention, including by proposing an insurance mechanism for the impacts of sea level rise

  • L&D discussed through language of “adverse effects” and “risk transfer”

  • Meetings were held on the possibility of an insurance mechanism

  • The phrase “loss and damage” was included in UNFCCC texts in Bali in 2007

 
  • Global North countries excluded Vanuatu’s proposal for L&D insurance from UNFCCC drafting negotiations

  • Parties agreed to include insurance as an instrument under Article 4.8 of the UNFCCC, but without a funding mechanism

  • Parties reached consensus to explore new issues through workshops outside of official UNFCCC negotiations

 
2007: Bali Action Plan 
2008–2013 2008: AOSIS proposal 
  • AOSIS again introduced a proposal for a compensation mechanism for L&D

  • AOSIS, the Least Developed Countries (LDC) Group, and the African Group of Negotiators formed a coalition on L&D, which the broader Group of 77 and China (G77 + China) bloc later supported

  • L&D coalition came prepared with robust proposals for texts at the 2013 Warsaw Conference

 
  • Global North countries agreed to address L&D only through discussion-based work programs

  • Global North countries, especially the United States, removed and weakened proposed texts for the WIM

  • The United Kingdom pulled funding for organizations advancing L&D efforts

  • Global North countries regularly connected and conflated L&D with adaptation

 
2010: L&D work program 
2012: L&D institutional arrangements 
2013: WIM established 
2014–2015 2014: L&D two-year work plan 
  • Strategically broadened the framing of L&D appeals

  • Increased media and nongovernmental organization attention to L&D

  • Succeeded in including a stand-alone article on L&D in the 2015 Paris Agreement (Article 8)

 
  • The nondifferentiation of the Paris Agreement broadened the scope of L&D to apply to all parties

  • The United States and Australia, among others, worked to prevent L&D from appearing in the Paris Agreement entirely

  • The United States, among others, foreclosed the possibility of linking L&D to liability and compensation in the Paris Agreement

 
2015: Paris Agreement 
2016 to present 2016: WIM review 
  • G77 + China repeatedly requested an agenda item on L&D at the Subsidiary Body meetings

  • Worked to consider L&D in the global stocktake

  • Worked to keep the WIM under the jurisdiction of the COP

  • Advocated for a financing mechanism and L&D Fund

  • G77 + China demanded a dedicated agenda item on L&D financing, which was accepted for discussion at COP27 in Sharm el-Sheikh

  • G77 + China succeeded in establishing a UNFCCC L&D finance facility at COP27

 
  • Global North countries opposed adding L&D as a stand-alone agenda item apart from the WIM

  • Global North countries stayed silent in L&D dialogues and discussions

  • Global North countries refused additional financing for L&D, including establishing a new fund

  • Global North countries focused their suggestions on weak and partial alternatives for finance (e.g., insurance)

  • Global North countries attempted to move the WIM to be exclusively under the Paris Agreement agenda to preclude claims of liability and compensation

  • The United States and Australia, among others, delayed deciding on financial arrangements for L&D until COP29 in 2024

 
2017: L&D five-year work plan 
2018: expert dialogue 
2022: L&D finance on agenda, parties agree to a L&D Fund 
PeriodYearsMilestonesL&D Finance AdvocatesL&D Finance Obstructionists
1991–2007 1991: AOSIS proposal 
  • Vanuatu/AOSIS worked to include L&D in the 1992 text of the UNFCCC Convention, including by proposing an insurance mechanism for the impacts of sea level rise

  • L&D discussed through language of “adverse effects” and “risk transfer”

  • Meetings were held on the possibility of an insurance mechanism

  • The phrase “loss and damage” was included in UNFCCC texts in Bali in 2007

 
  • Global North countries excluded Vanuatu’s proposal for L&D insurance from UNFCCC drafting negotiations

  • Parties agreed to include insurance as an instrument under Article 4.8 of the UNFCCC, but without a funding mechanism

  • Parties reached consensus to explore new issues through workshops outside of official UNFCCC negotiations

 
2007: Bali Action Plan 
2008–2013 2008: AOSIS proposal 
  • AOSIS again introduced a proposal for a compensation mechanism for L&D

  • AOSIS, the Least Developed Countries (LDC) Group, and the African Group of Negotiators formed a coalition on L&D, which the broader Group of 77 and China (G77 + China) bloc later supported

  • L&D coalition came prepared with robust proposals for texts at the 2013 Warsaw Conference

 
  • Global North countries agreed to address L&D only through discussion-based work programs

  • Global North countries, especially the United States, removed and weakened proposed texts for the WIM

  • The United Kingdom pulled funding for organizations advancing L&D efforts

  • Global North countries regularly connected and conflated L&D with adaptation

 
2010: L&D work program 
2012: L&D institutional arrangements 
2013: WIM established 
2014–2015 2014: L&D two-year work plan 
  • Strategically broadened the framing of L&D appeals

  • Increased media and nongovernmental organization attention to L&D

  • Succeeded in including a stand-alone article on L&D in the 2015 Paris Agreement (Article 8)

 
  • The nondifferentiation of the Paris Agreement broadened the scope of L&D to apply to all parties

  • The United States and Australia, among others, worked to prevent L&D from appearing in the Paris Agreement entirely

  • The United States, among others, foreclosed the possibility of linking L&D to liability and compensation in the Paris Agreement

 
2015: Paris Agreement 
2016 to present 2016: WIM review 
  • G77 + China repeatedly requested an agenda item on L&D at the Subsidiary Body meetings

  • Worked to consider L&D in the global stocktake

  • Worked to keep the WIM under the jurisdiction of the COP

  • Advocated for a financing mechanism and L&D Fund

  • G77 + China demanded a dedicated agenda item on L&D financing, which was accepted for discussion at COP27 in Sharm el-Sheikh

  • G77 + China succeeded in establishing a UNFCCC L&D finance facility at COP27

 
  • Global North countries opposed adding L&D as a stand-alone agenda item apart from the WIM

  • Global North countries stayed silent in L&D dialogues and discussions

  • Global North countries refused additional financing for L&D, including establishing a new fund

  • Global North countries focused their suggestions on weak and partial alternatives for finance (e.g., insurance)

  • Global North countries attempted to move the WIM to be exclusively under the Paris Agreement agenda to preclude claims of liability and compensation

  • The United States and Australia, among others, delayed deciding on financial arrangements for L&D until COP29 in 2024

 
2017: L&D five-year work plan 
2018: expert dialogue 
2022: L&D finance on agenda, parties agree to a L&D Fund 

L&D = loss and damage.

Table 2

Tactics Obstructing Loss and Damage Finance in the UNFCCC

 TacticDescriptionHard Versus SoftExample from L&D negotiations
Limiting the Scope 
Open rejection Refusing to agree to include proposed elements in draft texts Hard Keeping financial mechanisms like insurance out of the convention and denying any language that would imply compensation for climate impacts 
Agenda exclusion Rejecting proposed elements in negotiations Hard Excluding L&D from the agenda of Subsidiary Body meetings post-Paris 
Venue shifting Manipulating institutional infrastructure to restrict the scope of new and existing mechanisms Hard Working to shift L&D to sole jurisdiction under the Paris Agreement rather than the convention; passing finance discussions between negotiating tracks 
Denying credibility Reducing the legitimacy of an issue Hard Japan, the United States, and Australia failing to report on L&D in the enhanced finance transparency framework 
Reducing Transparency 
Omission of monitoring Impeding the collection of information on an issue to limit future consideration Hard Keeping L&D out of reporting requirements under the Paris Agreement and global stocktake 
Fortress building Excluding actors to limit the number of participants who make decisions, reducing transparency Hard Holding L&D negotiations in closed meetings 
Manipulating Language 
Issue narrowing Reducing the scope and framing of a concept Soft Discussing only discrete dimensions of L&D, e.g., insurance mechanisms 
Concept dilution Weakening the language of a proposed area of action Soft Diluting the language, e.g., “averting, minimizing, and addressing loss and damage” to expand the scope of the issue to include mitigation and adaptation actions 
Concept swapping Replacing broad issues with singular, acceptable components Soft Redefining L&D to mean disaster risk reduction and response, especially with insurance 
10 Strategic ambiguity Agreeing on text that allows parties to interpret the language according to their interests Soft The WIM and various documents relating to L&D discuss “support” for L&D without specifying what it involves or its nature, level, or sources 
Pushing Nontransformative Solutions 
11 All talk, no action Agreeing to discussions on topics to forestall action Soft Keeping L&D in workshops and work programs as long as possible 
12 Waiting on the science Delaying action via calls for more research Soft Calling for more research on the science of attribution of extreme events to climate change 
13 Policy perfectionism Delaying action via the pursuit of an unobjectionable policy solution, especially which avoids “fault” Soft Failing to establish a L&D fund with a funding mechanism based on responsibility, and a system to allocate funds in practice 
14 Redirecting attention Deflecting attention from nonaction in governance spaces to action elsewhere Soft The United States and other Global North countries highlighting places where they are already doing related work, such as contributing to regional risk-pooling schemes 
 TacticDescriptionHard Versus SoftExample from L&D negotiations
Limiting the Scope 
Open rejection Refusing to agree to include proposed elements in draft texts Hard Keeping financial mechanisms like insurance out of the convention and denying any language that would imply compensation for climate impacts 
Agenda exclusion Rejecting proposed elements in negotiations Hard Excluding L&D from the agenda of Subsidiary Body meetings post-Paris 
Venue shifting Manipulating institutional infrastructure to restrict the scope of new and existing mechanisms Hard Working to shift L&D to sole jurisdiction under the Paris Agreement rather than the convention; passing finance discussions between negotiating tracks 
Denying credibility Reducing the legitimacy of an issue Hard Japan, the United States, and Australia failing to report on L&D in the enhanced finance transparency framework 
Reducing Transparency 
Omission of monitoring Impeding the collection of information on an issue to limit future consideration Hard Keeping L&D out of reporting requirements under the Paris Agreement and global stocktake 
Fortress building Excluding actors to limit the number of participants who make decisions, reducing transparency Hard Holding L&D negotiations in closed meetings 
Manipulating Language 
Issue narrowing Reducing the scope and framing of a concept Soft Discussing only discrete dimensions of L&D, e.g., insurance mechanisms 
Concept dilution Weakening the language of a proposed area of action Soft Diluting the language, e.g., “averting, minimizing, and addressing loss and damage” to expand the scope of the issue to include mitigation and adaptation actions 
Concept swapping Replacing broad issues with singular, acceptable components Soft Redefining L&D to mean disaster risk reduction and response, especially with insurance 
10 Strategic ambiguity Agreeing on text that allows parties to interpret the language according to their interests Soft The WIM and various documents relating to L&D discuss “support” for L&D without specifying what it involves or its nature, level, or sources 
Pushing Nontransformative Solutions 
11 All talk, no action Agreeing to discussions on topics to forestall action Soft Keeping L&D in workshops and work programs as long as possible 
12 Waiting on the science Delaying action via calls for more research Soft Calling for more research on the science of attribution of extreme events to climate change 
13 Policy perfectionism Delaying action via the pursuit of an unobjectionable policy solution, especially which avoids “fault” Soft Failing to establish a L&D fund with a funding mechanism based on responsibility, and a system to allocate funds in practice 
14 Redirecting attention Deflecting attention from nonaction in governance spaces to action elsewhere Soft The United States and other Global North countries highlighting places where they are already doing related work, such as contributing to regional risk-pooling schemes 

As Table 1 shows, the first period began in 1991, when Vanuatu advanced a landmark proposal on behalf of AOSIS to establish an insurance mechanism funded by the most climate-culpable countries. The submission specified that the mechanism’s revenue should be “new, additional, and adequate,” with mandatory contributions from the Global North. Specifically, AOSIS suggested that 50 percent of the revenue should be based on a developed country’s gross national product (GNP) relative to the total GNP of all developed country parties, representing a country’s capacity. The remaining 50 percent of revenue would be based on a developed country’s carbon emissions, representing the country’s level of responsibility for climate change (INC 1991).

However, at the 1992 Earth Summit in Rio de Janeiro that followed the INCs, countries agreed to a convention text that contained a provision on insurance (Article 4.8) but excluded Vanuatu’s proposal. In the latter half of the 1990s, when COP meetings began, AOSIS continued advancing proposals for an insurance mechanism. Still, none were incorporated into official UNFCCC texts (Burkett 2015). In 2001, the IPCC’s Third Assessment Report revealed new evidence about the projected impacts of climate change in the Global South. In response to scientific findings and sustained advocacy from AOSIS, the phrase “loss and damage” appeared in the 2007 Bali Action Plan. In this text, parties agreed to explore “means to address loss and damage associated with climate change impacts in developing countries that are particularly vulnerable to the adverse effects of climate change” (UNFCCC 2012, Decision 1/CP.13, para. 1[c][iii]).

The second period began at COP14 in Poznań, Poland, in 2008, when AOSIS proposed a “multi-window facility” to address loss and damage. Their proposal called for a new fund that would compensate for all risks, including sea level rise, temperature increases, loss of land, damage to coral reefs, loss of fisheries, and salinization of aquifers (Earth Negotiations Bulletin 2008). Although parties did not include this proposal in the COP14 decisions, they agreed to discuss the facility at COP16 in Cancún in 2010 via a “work programme” (Ladislaw 2010). Parties delayed discussing specific elements of the work program until COP17 in Durban in 2011, where they ultimately called for a series of expert meetings. The following year, AOSIS established a coalition with the Least Developed Countries (LDCs) Group to increase the authority of their demands for loss and damage action. Bolivia, along with China, Ecuador, El Salvador, Guatemala, Nicaragua, the Philippines, and Thailand, also issued a statement calling for a “solidarity fund” to compensate vulnerable countries for “permanent” and “irreversible” loss and damage associated with climate change (Subsidiary Body for Implementation 2012, 6, 4). Despite the growing interest in establishing a loss and damage fund among G77 + China members, the United States and other countries in the Global North claimed it would inhibit adaptation efforts and place a monetary value on lives and livelihoods in vulnerable countries (McNamara 2014). Combative negotiations at COP18 in Doha in 2012 repeatedly stalled, especially on financial arrangements, as US representatives sought to remove the paragraph that would establish a funding mechanism for loss and damage. After thirty-six hours of nonstop deliberations in Doha, representatives agreed to further concretize the work program (McNamara 2014).

After COP18, representatives from the G77 + China, including AOSIS, the LDCs, and other loss and damage advocates, convened to develop a draft text for what would become the WIM. Civil society organizations and the media also generally supported Global South countries’ demands going into COP19 in Warsaw in 2013 (Allan and Hadden 2017). Just as the negotiations began, Super Typhoon Haiyan hit the Philippines. Haiyan’s devastation prompted Yeb Saño, a negotiator for the Philippines, to engage in a hunger strike that drew significant attention to the realities of climate impacts and created, according to one of our informants, a “public relations nightmare” for Global North countries that opposed a loss and damage mechanism. G77 + China negotiators walked out of one negotiation when they perceived that Australia’s delegation was not taking the talks seriously (Vidal 2013). Civil society observers noisily walked out the next day. Although parties eventually agreed to the text for the WIM, parties from the Global North succeeded in ensuring that the final text included only a work plan, without mention of a financial mechanism.

The establishment of the WIM in 2013 kicked off the third period, culminating in a stand-alone article on loss and damage in the 2015 Paris Agreement (UNFCCC 2015). The G77 + China arrived at the Paris talks with a draft text for Article 8 that avoided language on liability and compensation. Given Global North countries’ long-standing resistance to this language, this text constituted a significant political compromise from the bloc (Vanhala and Hestbaek 2016). By contrast, with support from other Global North countries, the United States presented a text that did not mention loss and damage. To address the North–South standoff on loss and damage, US climate envoy John Kerry held closed-door meetings with leaders from small island states to reach an agreement. Article 8 was included in the Paris decision document, but it was accompanied by the text of paragraph 51, which read, “Article 8 of the [Paris] Agreement does not involve or provide a basis for any liability or compensation” (UNFCCC 2016, Decision 1/CP.21). Paragraph 49 of the decision text also arguably weakens the WIM’s mandate from “avoid and reduce” loss and damage to “avert, minimize, and address” loss and damage (UNFCCC 2016, Decision 1/CP.21). Furthermore, parties did not formally connect Article 8 to the articles on finance and transparency, meaning that there is no mechanism under the Paris Agreement to raise or administer funding for loss and damage or to monitor progress on the issue in the regular global stocktaking of country actions.

In the fourth period, after Paris, the United States and its Global North allies worked to prevent loss and damage from progressing via the WIM and Article 8, including by avoiding discussing finance in the WIM’s rolling five-year work plan. The same countries also refused to consider loss and damage in finance negotiations, removed language on transparency for tracking loss and damage, and narrowed the frequency and scope of loss and damage discussions. They then attempted to bring the WIM under the exclusive authority of the Paris Agreement to make it beholden to paragraph 51. During the Suva Expert Dialogue at the forty-eighth session of the Subsidiary Bodies (SB48) in 2018, discussions around insurance dominated, even though, by that time, insurance was only a slice of the funding sought by the G77 + China for loss and damage. During the dialogue, Global North countries were uncharacteristically silent and largely abstained from the discussion. Later that year, Japan, the United States, and Australia failed to include loss and damage in their reporting under the enhanced finance transparency framework. When the G77 + China called for a “Glasgow Loss and Damage Facility” at COP26 in 2021, the United States, Australia, and the European Union (EU) agreed only to a dialogue on “arrangements for the funding of activities to avert, minimize and address loss and damage” to take place at midyear meetings from 2022 to 2024 (Rowling 2021).

After the first Glasgow Dialogue at SB56 in 2022, the G77 + China’s persistence for an agenda item on loss and damage finally paid off. The provisional agenda for COP27 included an item titled “matters related to funding arrangements to address loss and damage” under “matters relating to finance.” However, the United States and other Global North countries attempted to remove it in the days leading up to COP27. After overnight deliberations, parties changed the agenda item to “matters relating to funding arrangements responding to loss and damage associated with the adverse effects of climate change, including a focus on addressing loss and damage.” COP27 president Sameh Shoukry introduced the item with the caveat that “the outcomes of this agenda item are based on cooperation and facilitation, and do not involve liability or compensation,” echoing paragraph 51. Although Global North parties worked to codify President Shoukry’s verbal caveat in the decision text, they were unsuccessful. Ultimately, by the end of COP27, parties agreed to “establish new funding arrangements for assisting developing countries that are particularly vulnerable to the adverse effects of climate change” and to “establish a fund for responding to loss and damage whose mandate includes a focus on addressing loss and damage.”5 While the funding mechanism(s) (actual sources of money) have yet to be established, the decision to create them is the closest the UNFCCC has come in its thirty-year history to financing loss and damage.

A picture of obstruction emerges by tracing the negotiation processes and outcomes across four historical periods. Global North countries have actively and passively sought to avoid financial obligations for loss and damage via hard and soft negotiation tactics. Drawing on Lamb et al.’s (2020) typology of discourses of climate delay, we identify fourteen tactics countries have used to delay or prevent progress on loss and damage in the UNFCCC (see Table 2). These fall into four broad and interrelated categories: first, limiting the scope of the agenda items; second, reducing transparency by failing to monitor the problem; third, manipulating the meaning of the language; and fourth, pushing for nontransformative solutions.

Limiting the scope of loss and damage includes rejecting and excluding the issue from the agenda, passing it between negotiating tracks, and denying its legitimacy. Second, reducing transparency prevents parties from collecting information on the issue and making significant decisions in closed-door meetings. Third, countries manipulate loss and damage finance concepts. These tactics include replacing clear language with ambiguous text and narrowing, diluting, and swapping concepts. Finally, countries push nontransformative solutions, which include parties agreeing only to further discussions, calling for more scientific input, waiting on more “perfect” policy proposals, and diverting attention to progress on other issues. Countries often use these tactics simultaneously, which increases the difficulty of countering them.

The tactics used to obstruct loss and damage finance exist along a conceptual continuum of two ideal types, “hard” and “soft” bargaining (Dür and Mateo 2010). The “limiting the scope” and “reducing transparency” tactics fall toward the hard bargaining end of the spectrum. By contrast, the “manipulating language” and “pushing nontransformative solutions” tactics better align with soft bargaining. We categorized tactics into hard and soft ideal types based on whether they push uncooperative, hard-line answers to contentious proposals or promote seemingly cooperative solutions that offer a way to progress on the issues, even if those solutions effectively work to delay addressing the issue. Rather than placing the tactics along a continuum (for example, we might identify “open rejection” as “very hard” and “concept dilution” as “somewhat soft”), we maintain the broad categories of “hard” and “soft” to acknowledge that each tactic may vary in its “hardness” or “softness,” depending on that particular context. In short, this hard–soft characterization helps us assess when and how countries have been (un)cooperative on the issue of loss and damage finance over time. We argue that the United States’ red line on liability and compensation drove an “all hands on deck” strategy, where countries with vested interests in keeping loss and damage finance out of the UNFCCC did whatever they could to obstruct it. What follows is an elaboration on some of these tactics.

In each of the four periods, Global North countries endeavored to limit the scope of discussions on loss and damage finance. The hard tactics of agenda exclusion and open rejection, which countries often paired together, were both noncooperative and aggressive. The first instance of openly rejecting loss and damage finance (though this was not the operative language at the time) was when parties excluded Vanuatu’s 1991 proposal for an insurance mechanism from the convention text. More recently, countries openly rejected responsibility-based loss and damage finance via paragraph 51 of the Paris Agreement decision, which precluded the possibility of compensation for loss and damage. These actions kept loss and damage finance off the agenda, despite calls from developing country parties and activists (Climate Action Network 2022; McGrath 2022). Shifting the issue between negotiating tracks and denying its credibility only further limited the scope of the issue by shutting down discussions on it.

Countries have primarily resorted to hard tactics comprising “reducing transparency” in the fourth period in response to the incorporation of loss and damage in official texts via the WIM and the Paris Agreement. In particular, the structure of the Paris Agreement may have spurred these tactics since the primary accountability mechanisms for implementing the agreement are regular reviews of countries’ progress on climate action through “global stocktakes” (GSTs), along with reviews of national communications and biennial reviews. Because there is no connection between the articles on transparency and loss and damage in the Paris Agreement, Global North countries have repeatedly refused the Global South’s calls to include loss and damage in national reviews and the first GST in 2023, even as a sub-issue area under adaptation.

Global North countries have also used softer tactics to obstruct action on loss and damage. Soft tactics like “policy perfectionism” and “redirecting attention” give the appearance of advancing effective solutions that support the common good. For example, the United States agreed to participate in loss and damage discussions as they arose but often advocated for nontransformative solutions that did not include finance. One of the most significant and common soft tactics of loss and damage obstruction is relegating the issue to dialogues and work programs. This tactic exemplifies “all talk, no action,” where countries stymie concrete outcomes by delaying policy making without entirely rejecting the issue.

Key parties in the Global North consistently justify continuing work programs and dialogues by claiming that we need more scientific evidence and inputs (i.e., “waiting on the science”). The United States, for instance, used this tactic to obstruct AOSIS’s 2008 proposal for insurance and other loss and damage finance mechanisms (McNamara 2014; Siegele 2021a). Developed country parties also rejected Vanuatu’s 1991 proposal based on the need for more scientific evidence, according to an informant who participated in the INCs. The work program preceding the establishment of the WIM in 2013 was a rare exception that led to a concrete outcome, albeit without a financial mechanism. More recently, the Glasgow Dialogue, which began after COP26 in 2021, was initiated with no mandated outcome for loss and damage finance. This lack of mandate became a chief complaint of the G77 + China, animating its successful campaign to establish a new financing mechanism at COP27 by 2024.

The United States and other Global North countries also manipulated the core concepts of the issue. For example, developed country parties strongly supported the language of “averting, minimizing, and addressing” loss and damage. This language incorporates mitigation and adaptation actions that “avert” and “minimize” into loss and damage discussions. This move increases the risk of double-counting funding and minimizes the need for a new financial mechanism for loss and damage. Though undermining the phrasing preferred by the G77 + China, we characterize this tactic as soft because it is more conciliatory than outright rejection. The United States, among others, has also consistently swapped the concept of loss and damage with more narrow dimensions of the issue, such as disaster risk reduction or disaster insurance. This tactic avoids a broader discussion on loss and damage by focusing on a specific, less contentious aspect. Similarly, wealthy country parties have worked to narrow the finance issue to include only insurance mechanisms. We classify this tactic as soft because, at face value, it appears to be an attempt at cooperation.

Ultimately, these results demonstrate that the United States and other materially powerful countries in the Global North have employed both hard and soft bargaining tactics to obstruct loss and damage in the UNFCCC over time. While these materially powerful countries often use hard bargaining tactics (Dür and Mateo 2010), our findings support McKibben’s (2013) contention that the bargaining structure can minimize the effects of material power. In the consensus-based UNFCCC context, wealthy countries appear to use whatever bargaining tactic(s) might be most concession promoting at a given moment. The salience of climate justice as a moral imperative in climate negotiations may enhance the bargaining power of the G77 + China and its constituent groups when they employ injustice as a frame, making the relations of power between countries more complex than other international negotiations (Betzold 2010; Ciplet et al. 2015; Águeda Corneloup and Mol 2014; Rasheed 2019).

Our case study of obstruction to loss and damage finance spotlights the hard and soft bargaining tactics that Global North countries have used to forestall opportunities for climate justice in the UNFCCC. Although they caused the loss and damage occurring in the Global South, these countries refused for decades the creation of funding mechanisms to address it. We have demonstrated that the United States and other Global North countries have outright rejected and repeatedly stalled progress on loss and damage finance over more than thirty years of climate negotiations. While the requirement of consensus among parties in the UNFCCC negotiations allows countries to easily obstruct an issue by withdrawing their support, our analysis shows that it also gives countries with less geopolitical power leverage to assert their priorities. The diversity of tactics we have identified supports the idea that materially powerful countries are, therefore, forced to take nuanced approaches in the face of contestation from subordinate actors in climate negotiations (McKibben 2013).

Our study contributes to a growing literature on climate obstruction. The obstruction tactics we identify expand on, for example, Lamb et al.’s (2020) typology of delaying mitigation action. Rather than contradicting existing frameworks for understanding obstruction, we believe that each new case study of an arena of climate decision-making will reveal the particularities of obstruction in different contexts, building a nuanced landscape of climate obstruction that is both far reaching and specific. For example, tactics of “climate doomism” that Global North countries use for mitigation (Lamb et al. 2020) might actually work to bolster Global South countries’ arguments for a loss and damage fund, making them inappropriate for this context.

For loss and damage, greater awareness of the tactics used to block or delay action on finance may serve actors who are seeking to advance equitable climate solutions in the UNFCCC. Spotlighting obstructionism helps reduce the effectiveness of these tactics. This typology could also serve as the basis for similar typologies tailored to other global governance contexts beyond the UNFCCC. For example, financial compensation for damages is also a matter of concern for countries in the Global South under the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade and World Trade Organization agreements; nuclear arms accords; and, of course, development finance expectations and systems at the World Bank Group, the International Monetary Fund, regional development banks, and so on. Proposals of developing nations in those venues advance or stall, depending in part on tactics taken by both sides.

Scholars can build on this study in several ways. First, we need more analysis of the domestic determinants of the strategies countries use in international negotiations, particularly in powerful countries like the United States (Bailer 2012; Dür and Mateo 2010; Falkner 2012; Wagner 1999; Weiler 2012). For example, it would be helpful to account for how industrial interests shaped the United States’ early opposition to responsibility-based mechanisms in the UNFCCC in the 1990s. Second, we do not understand the conditions under which specific obstructionist tactics are used or are more likely to succeed. Understanding how negotiation tactics emerge among negotiators, countries, and coalitions, or what happens when various tactics come into conflict in settings like the UNFCCC, could shed light on how and why international negotiations progress the way they do.

Last, the parties’ recent decision to establish loss and damage financial arrangements, including a fund, under the UNFCCC raises a critical question: what form will obstruction take moving forward? Fundamental equity issues related to the yet-to-be-named loss and damage fund remain unresolved, including who will pay, how much, and using what sources of funding. At the time of writing, parties have yet to make pledges aside from very modest external institutional funds promised by the leaders of Scotland, Belgium, Denmark, and a few other countries. Ultimately, obstruction will likely continue in the UNFCCC on this and other climate justice–related issues. Identifying and overcoming these tactics will only become more urgent as climate disasters proliferate.

We thank the Climate Social Science Network for supporting this research and Perry World House for covering the cost of open access publication. We also thank the special issue editors—Lisa Vanhala, Elisa Calliari, and Adelle Thomas—for bringing together this great group of articles and for their early comments on this project, along with the rest of the participants at the June 2022 special issue workshop at University College London. Thanks to the GEP editors and anonymous reviewers for their valuable feedback on this manuscript.

1. 

The capitalization of the phrase loss and damage is a subject of political debate (see Hartz 2023). We use lowercase spelling to ease reading and follow the capitalization norms on similar terms, such as adaptation and mitigation.

2. 

We refer to “Global North” countries broadly to indicate wealthy countries, often referred to as “developed” countries or “Annex I” countries in the UNFCCC arena. Many of these countries are also included in the “Umbrella Group” coordinating group.

3. 

See https://cssn.org/, last accessed May 30, 2023.

4. 

We thank the anonymous reviewer who drew our attention to this point.

5. 

As of this writing, final decision texts have not been released. The draft text for Decision -/CP.27 -/CMA.4, “Funding Arrangements for Responding to Loss and Damage Associated with the Adverse Effects of Climate Change, Including a Focus on Addressing Loss and Damage,” can be found at https://unfccc.int/documents/624440, last accessed May 30, 2023.

Adelman
,
Sam
.
2016
.
Climate Justice, Loss and Damage and Compensation for Small Island Developing States
.
Journal of Human Rights and the Environment
7
(
1
):
32
53
.
Adler
,
Ben
.
2015
.
Here’s Why the Words “Loss and Damage” Are Causing Such a Fuss at the Paris Climate Talks
.
Grist
, .
Águeda Corneloup
,
Inés de
, and
Arthur P. J.
Mol
.
2014
.
Small Island Developing States and International Climate Change Negotiations: The Power of Moral “Leadership.”
International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law, and Economics
14
(
3
):
281
297
.
Allan
,
Jen Iris
, and
Jennifer
Hadden
.
2017
.
Exploring the Framing Power of NGOs in Global Climate Politics
.
Environmental Politics
26
(
4
):
600
620
.
Bailer
,
Stefanie
.
2012
.
Strategy in the Climate Change Negotiations: Do Democracies Negotiate Differently?
Climate Policy
12
(
5
):
534
551
.
Betzold
,
Carola
.
2010
.
“Borrowing” Power to Influence International Negotiations: AOSIS in the Climate Change Regime, 1990–1997
.
Politics
30
(
3
):
131
148
.
Boyd
,
Emily
,
Rachel A.
James
,
Richard G.
Jones
,
Hannah R.
Young
, and
Friederike E. L.
Otto
.
2017
.
A Typology of Loss and Damage Perspectives
.
Nature Climate Change
7
(
10
):
723
729
.
Burkett
,
Maxine
.
2015
.
Rehabilitation: A Proposal for a Climate Compensation Mechanism for Small Island States
.
Santa Clara Journal of International Law
13
(
1
):
Article 5
.
Burkett
,
Maxine
.
2016
.
Reading Between the Red Lines: Loss and Damage and the Paris Outcome
.
Climate Law
6
(
1–2
):
118
129
.
Calliari
,
Elisa
.
2018
.
Loss and Damage: A Critical Discourse Analysis of Parties’ Positions in Climate Change Negotiations
.
Journal of Risk Research
21
(
6
):
725
747
.
Calliari
,
E.
,
O.
Serdeczny
, and
L.
Vanhala
.
2020
.
Making Sense of the Politics in the Climate Change Loss and Damage Debate
.
Global Environmental Change
64
:
102133
. ,
[PubMed]
Climate Action Network
.
2022
.
European Union’s Hypocrisy Exposed at Bonn Climate Conference
. .
Ciplet
,
David
,
J. Timmons
Roberts
, and
Mizan
Khan
.
2015
.
Power in a Warming World: The New Global Politics of Climate Change and the Remaking of Environmental Inequality
.
Cambridge, MA
:
MIT Press
.
Depledge
,
Joanna
.
2008
.
Striving for No: Saudi Arabia in the Climate Change Regime
.
Global Environmental Poltics
8
(
4
):
9
35
.
Dür
,
Andreas
, and
Gemma
Mateo
.
2010
.
Bargaining Power and Negotiation Tactics: The Negotiations on the EU’s Financial Perspective, 2007–13
.
Journal of Common Market Studies
48
(
3
):
557
578
.
Earth Negotiations Bulletin
.
2008
.
Summary of the Fourteenth Conference of the Parties to the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change and Fourth Meeting of Parties to the Kyoto Protocol: 1–12 December 2008
. .
Ekberg
,
Kristoffer
,
Bernhard
Forchtner
, and
Martin
Hultman
.
2023
.
Climate Obstruction: How Denial, Delay and Inaction Are Heating the Planet
. 1st ed.
New York, NY
:
Routledge
.
Falkner
,
Robert
.
2012
.
Global Environmentalism and the Greening of International Society
.
International Affairs
88
(
3
):
503
522
.
Falzon
,
Danielle
,
J. Timmons
Roberts
,
Fred
Shaia
,
Md. Fahad
Hossain
,
Stacy-ann
Robinson
,
Mizan
Khan
, and
David
Ciplet
.
2022
.
Loss and Damage Finance: Four Periods of Obstruction in the UN Climate Negotiations
.
Climate Social Science Network Briefing
.
Galvão Ferreira
,
Patrícia
.
2021
.
Arrested Development: The Late and Inequitable Integration of Loss and Damage Finance into the UNFCCC
. In
Research Handbook on Climate Change Law and Loss and Damage
, edited by
Meinhard
Doelle
and
Sara
Seck
,
127
148
.
London, UK
:
Edward Elgar
.
Green
,
Jessica F.
2020
.
Less Talk, More Walk: Why Climate Change Demands Activism in the Academy
.
Daedalus
149
(
4
):
151
162
.
Gupta
,
Joyeeta
.
2012
.
Negotiating Challenges and Climate Change
.
Climate Policy
12
(
5
):
630
644
.
Hartz
,
Friederike
.
2023
.
Does orthography matter? Representations and understandings of loss(es) and damage(s) in the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change
.
(This issue.)
Intergovernmental Negotiating Committee
.
1991
.
Vanuatu: Draft Annex Relating to Article 23 (Insurance) for Inclusion in the Revised Single Text on Elements Relating to Mechanisms
. .
Ladislaw
,
Sarah
.
2010
.
Cancun Climate Negotiation
.
Center for Strategic & International Studies
.
December 15. Available at: https://www.csis.org/analysis/cancun-climate-negotiation, last accessed May 30, 2023
.
Lamb
,
William F.
,
Giulio
Mattioli
,
Sebastian
Levi
,
J. Timmons
Roberts
,
Stuart
Capstick
,
Felix
Creutzig
,
Jan C.
Minx
,
Finn
Müller-Hansen
,
Trevor
Culhane
, and
Julia K.
Steinberger
.
2020
.
Discourses of Climate Delay
.
Global Sustainability
3
:
E17
.
Levy
,
David L.
, and
Daniel
Egan
.
1998
.
Capital Contests: National and Transnational Channels of Corporate Influence on the Climate Change Negotiations
.
Politics and Society
26
(
3
):
337
361
.
Linnerooth-Bayer
,
JoAnne
,
Swenja
Surminski
,
Laurens M.
Bouwer
,
Ilan
Noy
, and
Reinhard
Mechler
.
2019
.
Insurance as a Response to Loss and Damage?
In
Loss and Damage from Climate Change
, edited by
Reinhard
Mechler
,
Laurens M.
Bouwer
,
Thomas
Schinko
,
Swenja
Surminski
, and
JoAnne
Linnerooth-Bayer
,
483
512
.
Cham, Switzerland
:
Springer
.
Mace
,
M. J.
, and
Roda
Verheyen
.
2016
.
Loss, Damage and Responsibility After COP21: All Options Open for the Paris Agreement
.
Review of European, Comparative, and International Environmental Law
25
(
2
):
197
214
.
Martill
,
Benjamin
, and
Uta
Staiger
.
2021
.
Negotiating Brexit: The Cultural Sources of British Hard Bargaining
.
Journal of Common Market Studies
59
(
2
):
261
277
.
McGrath
,
Matt
.
2022
.
Climate Change: Rich Nations Accused of “Betrayal” at Bonn Talks
.
BBC News
, .
McKibben
,
Heather Elko
.
2013
.
The Effects of Structures and Power on State Bargaining Strategies
.
American Journal of Political Science
57
(
2
):
411
427
.
McNamara
,
Karen Elizabeth
.
2014
.
Exploring Loss and Damage at the International Climate Change Talks
.
International Journal of Disaster Risk Science
5
(
3
):
242
246
.
McNamara
,
Karen E.
, and
Guy
Jackson
.
2019
.
Loss and Damage: A Review of the Literature and Directions for Future Research
.
WIREs Climate Change
10
(
2
):
e564
.
Meckling
,
Jonas
.
2011
.
The Globalization of Carbon Trading: Transnational Business Coalitions in Climate Politics
.
Global Environmental Politics
11
(
2
):
26
50
.
Mildenberger
,
Matto
.
2020
.
Carbon Captured: How Business and Labor Control Climate Politics
.
Cambridge, MA
:
MIT Press
.
Newell
,
Peter
, and
Matthew
Paterson
.
2010
.
Climate Capitalism: Global Warming and the Transformation of the Global Economy
.
Cambridge, UK
:
Cambridge University Press
.
Odell
,
John
.
2013
.
Negotiation and Bargaining
. In
Handbook of International Relations
, 2nd ed., edited by
Walter
Carlsnaes
,
Thomas
Risse
, and
Beth A.
Simmons
,
379
400
.
London, UK
:
Sage
.
Odell
,
John
.
2018
.
Negotiating the World Economy
.
Cornell Studies in Political Economy
.
Ithaca, NY
:
Cornell University Press
.
Odell
,
John S.
, and
Dustin
Tingley
.
2016
.
Negotiating Agreements in International Relations
. In
Political Negotiation: A Handbook
, edited by
Cathie J.
Martin
and
Jane J.
Mansbridge
.
Washington, DC
:
Brookings Institution Press
.
Page
,
Edward A.
, and
Clare
Heyward
.
2017
.
Compensating for Climate Change Loss and Damage
.
Political Studies
65
(
2
):
356
372
.
Rasheed
,
Athaulla A.
2019
.
Role of Small Islands in UN Climate Negotiations: A Constructivist Viewpoint
.
International Studies
56
(
4
):
215
235
.
Risse
,
Thomas
.
2000
.
“Let’s Argue!”: Communicative Action in World Politics
.
International Organization
54
(
1
):
1
39
.
Roberts
,
Erin
, and
Saleemul
Huq
.
2015
.
Coming Full Circle: The History of Loss and Damage Under the UNFCCC
.
International Journal of Global Warming
8
(
2
):
141
157
.
Roberts
,
J. Timmons
, and
Bradley C.
Parks
.
2007
.
A Climate of Injustice: Global Inequality, North–South Politics, and Climate Policy
.
Global Environmental Accord
.
Cambridge, MA
:
MIT Press
.
Robinson
,
Stacy-ann
, and
D’Arcy
Carlson
.
2021
.
A Just Alternative to Litigation: Applying Restorative Justice to Climate-Related Loss and Damage
.
Third World Quarterly
42
(
6
):
1384
1395
.
Rowling
,
Megan
.
2021
.
Climate “Loss and Damage” Earns Recognition but Little Action in COP26 Deal
.
Reuters
, .
Subsidiary Body for Implementation
.
2012
.
Views and Information from Parties and Relevant Organizations on the Possible Elements to Be Included in the Recommendations on Loss and Damage in Accordance with Decision 1/CP.16. Submissions from Parties and Relevant Organizations. Addendum
.
Available at: https://unfccc.int/documents/7491, last accessed May 30, 2023
.
Siegele
,
Linda
.
2021a
.
Loss and Damage Under the Convention
. In
Research Handbook on Climate Change Law and Loss and Damage
, edited by
Meinhard
Doelle
and
Sara
Seck
,
75
99
.
London, UK
:
Edward Elgar
.
Siegele
,
Linda
.
2021b
.
Loss and Damage Under the Paris Agreement
. In
Research Handbook on Climate Change Law and Loss and Damage
, edited by
Meinhard
Doelle
and
Sara
Seck
,
100
126
.
London, UK
:
Edward Elgar
.
Stokes
,
Leah Cardamore
.
2020
.
Short Circuiting Policy: Interest Groups and the Battle over Clean Energy and Climate Policy in the American States
.
Oxford Studies in Postwar American Political Development
.
New York, NY
:
Oxford University Press
.
United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
.
1992
.
United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
.
Available at: https://unfccc.int/sites/default/files/conveng.pdf, last accessed May 30, 2023
.
United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
.
2012
.
Theme III—The Role of the Convention in Enhancing the Implementation of Approaches to Address Loss and Damage Associated with the Adverse Effects of Climate Change. Decision 1/CP.13
. .
United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
.
2015
.
Paris Agreement
. .
United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
.
2016
.
Report of the Conference of the Parties on Its Twenty-First Session, Held in Paris from 30 November to 13 December 2015, Addendum, Part Two: Action Taken by the Conference of the Parties at Its Twenty-First Session
.
Available at: https://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2015/cop21/eng/10a01.pdf, last accessed May 30, 2023
.
Vanhala
,
Lisa
, and
Cecilie
Hestbaek
.
2016
.
Framing Climate Change Loss and Damage in UNFCCC Negotiations
.
Global Environmental Politics
16
(
4
):
111
129
.
Vidal
,
John
.
2013
.
Poor Countries Walk Out of UN Climate Talks as Compensation Row Rumbles On
.
Guardian
,
November 20, sec. Global Development. Available at: https://www.theguardian.com/global-development/2013/nov/20/climate-talks-walk-out-compensation-un-warsaw, last accessed May 30, 2023
.
Wagner
,
Lynn M.
1999
.
Negotiations in the UN Commission on Sustainable Development: Coalitions, Processes, and Outcomes
.
International Negotiation
4
(
2
):
107
131
.
Walton
,
Richard E.
, and
Robert B.
McKersie
.
1965
.
A Behavioral Theory of Labor Negotiations: An Analysis of a Social Interaction System
.
Ithaca, NY
:
ILR Press
.
Weiler
,
Florian
.
2012
.
Determinants of Bargaining Success in the Climate Change Negotiations
.
Climate Policy
12
(
5
):
552
574
.
Weise
,
Zia
, and
Karl
Mathiesen
.
2021
.
EU, US Block Effort for Climate Disaster Funding at COP26
.
POLITICO
(blog), November 13. Available at: https://www.politico.eu/article/eu-us-block-financial-support-climate-change-cop26/, last accessed May 30, 2023
.
Winham
,
Gilbert R.
1986
.
International Trade and the Tokyo Round Negotiation
.
Princeton, NJ
:
Princeton University Press
.

Author notes

*

Corresponding author: [email protected]

This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. For a full description of the license, please visit https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/legalcode.