Preferences are a crucial element for analyzing decision making and negotiations, but knowledge about which factors determine these preferences is sparse. Some quantitative and qualitative studies of European Union (EU) negotiations have assumed that the negotiation conflict dimensions in intergovernmental negotiations reflect market-versus-regulation approaches as well as a north–south dimension. In this study, I demonstrate that these findings can be extended to show that the relevant determining factors for negotiation positions are economic structural variables and the degree to which a country benefits from the EU. Furthermore, the domestic interests of EU governments better explain a government’s interest in some specific issues, such as consumer protection or fishery policies, than do their partisan preferences. Moreover, I am able to show that in frequent negotiations, such as EU Council of Ministers negotiations, sincere preferences dominate; however, some factors, such as extreme salience, can increase the likelihood that a minister will choose a less sincere strategic position such as an extreme position.

During his two periods in office, the German Social Democratic chancellor, Gerhard Schröder, earned his nickname “Auto-Kanzler” because of his fierce defense of the German car industry’s interests in two major legislative discussions at the European Union (EU) level — the end-of-life vehicle directive (European Union Council of Ministers 1997) and the takeover directive (European Union Council of Ministers 1995). In the former proposal, the European Commission had suggested a law that would have made vehicle dismantling more environmentally friendly and encouraged car producers to develop cars that were easier to recycle. In the latter law, a legal framework for company takeovers was proposed by the commission that was intended to protect the interests of shareholders. The German opposition caused either the serious delay or the outright failure of these environmentally protective and consumer-friendly commission proposals because of the pressure from lobby groups.

These cases serve as examples that a government can quite predictably behave in the interests of a national industry within the EU, regardless of its partisan preference; in this case, the connection between Schröder and Volkswagen was particularly close because the German car producer is located in Schröder’s home region, where it is a major employer. This behavior by the German government thus suggests that the negotiation positions of governments in the EU Council of Ministers can be explained by structural and domestic interests and that the governments’ partisan orientations play only a secondary role. This is somewhat surprising considering that the left–right cleavage is still the dominant structuring principle in European party politics, and the ideological orientation of parties to a great extent determines whether they are elected for office or not.

Academic interest in preferences, negotiations, and conflict dimensions and their relevance to the activities of the EU has increased markedly in the last decade (Moravcsik 1998; Mattila 2009). Negotiation researchers and others who analyze decision making are particularly interested in what the conflict dimensions in the EU actually are and how the negotiation positions in the EU Council of Ministers negotiations can be explained. Does conflict arise because EU governments have different positions on European integration, because they have different economic or societal interests to defend, or because they are more or less left or right wing? Are their negotiation positions driven by national industries or by the public’s opinion of the EU integration process? Taking into account that the EU Council of Ministers is designed to represent the member states’ interests (in contrast to the European Parliament of the EU where party groups debate legislative proposals and where party ideologies dominate), it could be expected that structural and societal interests would be represented (Hix and Noury 2006).

As for the Council of Ministers, where EU governments negotiate day-to-day legislative issues ranging from the ingredients in honey to environmental standards, opinions diverge as to whether partisan cleavages (Mattila 2004), market-versus-regulation preferences (Thomson, Boerefijn, and Stokman 2004), or financial considerations (Zimmer, Schneider, and Dobbins 2005) are more relevant explanations of negotiation positions.1 I discuss this in the first part of this study, arguing that examining negotiation positions according to policy areas indicates that it is the interests of national industries and constituencies and not so much the left–right orientation of governments that matter most in Council of Ministers negotiations. Because I concede, however, that some strategic considerations may also influence the choice of a position — especially when particularly important topics from the point of view of a negotiator are discussed — I also consider whether an extreme position can be explained on the basis of strategic considerations. My corresponding results indicate that extreme positions are especially taken by powerful member states and by governments that have a particularly strong interest in the negotiation issue at hand. These findings contribute to ongoing debates about the determinants of preferences (Frieden 1999) and the difficulty of distinguishing between sincere and strategic preferences in international negotiations (Bueno de Mesquita 2004; Achen 2006).

International relations theories and negotiation analyses use the preferences of states as a crucial starting point for the investigation of the relations and interactions of governments in the international sphere. For analytical clarity, I distinguish between interests, preferences, and negotiation positions as follows: by “preferences,” I refer to the underlying interests of a state, which are its long-term goals or, in game-theoretic terms, the way a state would order the nodes of a game tree (Frieden 1999). A negotiation position instead encompasses these preferences as well as the strategic considerations that arise when a negotiator takes the positions of other players into account (Morrow 1999). This might mean that a government strategically “exaggerates” its preference, adopting an extreme position with the intention of dragging the other negotiating states toward its actual position. In the following section, I briefly discuss theories from international relations and the negotiation literature relevant to analyzing negotiation positions.

International relations scholars have formulated several theories to explain the determinants of negotiation positions. Based on the assumption that states behave like “billiard balls” in an international system, “realists” argue that the preferences of states result from their positions in the state system. According to this theory, for example, national military capacity can be seen as a means of signifying the power position of a state (Morgenthau 1967). In the realists’ view, however, neither policy concerns nor domestic interests influence the position of a state in the international system. “Neo-realists” subsequently developed this argument further, arguing that military resources are not the only determining factor of a state’s position, but that economic interdependencies and domestic factors can also exercise a strong influence (Keohane and Nye 1989).

“Liberal” theorists attribute an even stronger influence to domestic variables, asserting that they are the defining elements of a state’s interest. In line with the liberal institutionalist approach, Andrew Moravcsik (1997: 518) defined states’ interests as an aggregate of individual interests and explained that states represent “some subset of domestic society.” Thus, states’ interests are composed, on the one hand, by their fundamental preferences determined by structural economic interests, and on the other hand, by social interests that are defined by their domestic desires. This argument is built on the idea that the more privileged a social group is, the more likely it is to have its interests well represented within the national government (Moravcsik 1997). Thomas Schelling (1960) developed the term “paradox of weakness” to describe the possible effect of domestic groups upon international negotiators, explaining how a government negotiator can jockey for concessions at the international level by convincing the other party how critical and skeptical his domestic constituency is. The history of EU negotiations reveals an abundance of cases in which such concessions were made, for example, the granting of the Danish and British exemptions from the Maastricht Treaty obligations on social policy.

In a similar vein, Simon Hug (2003) criticized intergovernmental analytical approaches in the EU literature for ignoring the link between pivotal actors at the domestic level and preferences declared at the international level, arguing that international bargains often have to be ratified at the domestic level. Likewise, in his study of preference formation in the negotiations regarding the International Treaty on the Seabed Convention, Thomas Bräuninger (2001) was able to show that domestic preferences determined states’ preferences to a large degree.

In addition to structural and social interests, the partisan preferences of governments are also considered relevant for explaining how governments choose policies (Schmidt 1996). Because the ideological positions of parties help distinguish them from their competitors in national elections, we might expect partisan orientation to influence a government’s negotiation position. Philip Manow, Armin Schäfer, and Hendrik Zorn (2008) were able to show that in the context of European Council summits, the left–right orientation of EU governments — in particular, the shift from the political right in the 1950s toward the left in the 1990s — can help explain changes in EU social policy. Similarly, regarding EU environmental policy, Christian Jensen and Jae-Jae Spoon (2011) have shown that Green Party representation in a government predicts that government’s progress toward meeting Kyoto Protocol targets for reducing the production of greenhouse gases. It remains unknown whether this effect holds only for high-level EU summits, however, considering that they are concerned with more general policy guidelines in contrast to the Council of Ministers negotiations under discussion in this study, which are more concerned with discussing day-to-day legislation. But, Michael Bechtel and Gerald Schneider (2010) have shown the importance of economic interests even at the summit level.

As far as the EU Council of Ministers is concerned, opinions diverge regarding the meaning of negotiation positions and what determines them. In their analyses of final votes in the Council of Ministers, both Sara Hagemann (2007) and Mikki Mattila (2004) found the left-wing versus right-wing leaning of EU governments to be an important independent predictor of voting behavior. Sara Hagemann and Bjorn Hoyland (2008) reached a similar conclusion. Their study, however, does not control for the possible impact of other factors. Indeed, other studies have identified a north–south dimension (Mattila 2009); preferences based purely on north–south geography do not seem to support any existing theory and may reflect underlying structural interests, such as the presence of certain industries and populations that are located in the same geographical regions.

Similarly, when examining the original negotiation positions at the beginning of the council discussion from the “Decision Making in the EU” (DEU) data set (Thomson et al. 2006),2 other researchers suggested that the political dimensions break down along a north–south dimension (Thomson, Boerefijn, and Stokman 2004; Kaeding and Selck 2005; Zimmer, Schneider, and Dobbins 2005). (The DEU data set includes the negotiation positions of the then fifteen EU member states on sixty-six legislative proposals.) A preference for regulatory versus market-based solutions (Thomson, Boerefijn, and Stokman 2004) and a redistributive dimension (Zimmer, Schneider, and Dobbins 2005) were also identified. These results based on the DEU data set thus suggest that the structural and social interests of the states — to use Moravcsik’s terminology — better explain the negotiation position of an EU government in council negotiations than do partisan preferences.

Finally, scholars who used survey data regarding communication patterns in the council (Elgström et al. 2002; Naurin and Lindahl 2008) found that more communications occurred between countries in the same region than between governments that shared a more left- or right-wing ideology.

None of these analyses has investigated, in detail at least, which domestic preferences are actually instrumental in terms of shaping certain negotiation positions. This study thus adds to these previous analyses by examining which particular domestic interests explain negotiation positions, as well as by investigating the possible role of strategic positions.

One explanation for why governments might choose not to directly represent their sincere structural interests lies in their use of tactics. Strategies reflect an actor’s overall attempts to influence negotiation circumstances; tactics are those actions he or she takes to react to other players’ positions; both are chosen according to the information an actor has about the other players (Morrow 1994: 66). These “signaling games” characterize situations in which an actor with private information sends a signal to his or her counterpart to which that counterpart is then expected to react to (Spence 1973; Gibbons 1997; Morrow 1999). The results of strategic actions consequently depend on the asymmetrical distribution of information and upon the goals and strategies of other players. Such actions could include a bluff (i.e., signaling a more extreme position than is actually intended).

In the case of EU negotiations, Gerald Schneider and Lars-Erik Cederman (1994) demonstrated that adopting an extreme position can be an effective tool for achieving a particular goal in the European Council. Negotiation research has confirmed this; some researchers have found that a strategy of starting tough and then gradually making concessions can be a more effective means of reaching an optimal division of resources, than a strategy in which a softer position is maintained throughout the negotiations (Rubin and Brown 1975). Similarly, negotiation studies have shown that bold strategies can be worth the effort because higher aspirations often lead to higher payoffs (Zetik and Stuhlmacher 2002; Wolfe and McGinn 2005). The effect of taking a hard initial bargaining stance was found to be even stronger when the counterparts adopted a softer and more lenient strategy and were prepared to make concessions (Rubin and Brown 1975). Of course, choosing a more extreme position can be less efficient when all negotiators employ that same strategy because agreements become less likely in such cases (Fisher, Ury, and Patton 1991).

Such a threat failed, for example, during the mad cow disease crisis when the British used a blocking strategy that backfired when it was met by strong resistance, which is not an uncommon response. Out of anger over the embargo against British beef, the British delegation refused to agree to several unrelated legislative proposals in May and June 1996 that required unanimity (Dinan 1999). Because the other fourteen governments showed an even higher degree of determination to continue the beef blockade, the British government was eventually forced to give up its blocking strategy. The high degree of resolve of the fourteen counterparts arose, most likely, from the widespread public fear of contaminated beef in the EU.

As described, actions can reflect sincere preferences or strategic considerations. In the above-mentioned example, the British government treated the export of beef as a salient issue and thus assumed an extreme position with regard to unrelated EU proposals. In particular, this blockade was probably an exaggerated preference and thus not a sincere position. It is hardly ever possible to distinguish exactly between sincere and insincere strategies, and we can thus merely assume that extreme positions may not necessarily reflect a sincere preference only because assuming an extreme position is an established negotiation practice that can reflect strategic as well as sincere considerations by a negotiating government.

Having discussed the variables “structural interests,”“domestic interests” (or social interests in Moravcsik’s terminology), “partisan orientations,” and “strategies” as possible determinants of the preference of a government in Council of Ministers negotiations, I will now use the first part of my empirical analysis to expand the previous analyses of Christina Zimmer, Gerald Schneider, and Michael Dobbins (2005) and Robert Thomson and his colleagues (2004) and show how a more detailed analysis of domestic interests can explain state preferences.

Based on the liberal intergovernmentalist approach, I postulate in the first of my four hypotheses that EU governments assume positions that reflect their structural (economic or redistributive) interests (Moravcsik 1997) in Council of Ministers negotiations:

Hypothesis One: Positions in Council of Ministers negotiations reflect the structural interests of the individual EU member states.

Apart from economic interests, I also propose that various domestic-level societal interests influence governments’ positions in EU negotiations. Governments may adopt a position that directly represents the opinion of the citizens or of important domestic stakeholders to demonstrate to the domestic constituency that its European-level representative actively defends their interests.

Hypothesis Two: Positions in Council of Ministers negotiations reflect domestic interests in the EU member states.

As a control variable, I will account for the partisan orientation of the EU governments at the time of the debate about the proposals.

If one allows for the possibility that bargaining positions reflect negotiation strategies, it should be stated that employing such strategies can come at significant cost. If negotiators exaggerate their positions or fail to honor commitments, they risk losing their credibility and thus losing their threat potential (Hovi 1998). So, while they may be strongly tempted to invent a constrained win set which is the set of all possible agreements that would find a majority among the constituents (Putnam 1988), they also confront the danger a “bluff” will be detected by other parties (Schelling 1960) — especially in an information-rich environment such as the Council of Ministers, where it is not uncommon for negotiators to meet on a daily basis.

Therefore, I postulate that strategies such as assuming an extreme position are only used in exceptionally difficult negotiation situations. For example, in 2000, the British government successfully obtained a number of concessions in the lengthy and tough negotiations over the EU directive on artists’ resale rights by assuming an isolated extreme position at the end of the opinion continuum (European Union Council of Ministers 1996).3 Furthermore, this success could be interpreted as proof of how a tough and intransigent extreme position can pay off in legislative negotiations in the EU: because of the outlying position of the United Kingdom, the final common position of the council supported the notion of a maximum ceiling on artist royalties, thus, seriously distorting the original idea of the proposal, which had wanted to treat artists more favorably at the cost of the auction houses. The British delegation achieved special consideration of its “vital interest” in protecting the future of the British auction houses Sotheby’s and Christie’s where 90 percent of the European auction sales occur.

Thus, my third hypothesis is as follows:

Hypothesis Three: The more intense the interest of a member state in a particular negotiation issue, the more likely that state will be to assume an extreme position Council of Ministers negotiations.

Another possible variable relates to each state’s voting power within the council. Some member states may consider whether they can swing a final vote with their number of votes. In such a situation, large member states might be tempted to assume a position far from the median opinion if they perceive a greater chance of preventing a winning majority in qualified majority voting, in contrast to smaller states whose voices might more easily be ignored. In order to see whether exogenous power resources (Bailer 2004), such as the number of votes, influence the choice of an extreme position, I test the fourth and final hypothesis:

Hypothesis Four: The more powerful a EU member state, the more likely it will be to assume an extreme position in Council of Ministers negotiations.

So far, conducting studies on EU Council of Ministers negotiations has been made more difficult because of the extreme secrecy that shrouds Council of Ministers negotiations (Gabel, Hix, and Schneider 2002). A few studies have used the final voting records (Mattila and Lane 2001; Mattila 2004, 2006, 2007; Hayes-Renshaw, Van Aken, and Wallace 2006) and formal statements (Hagemann 2007; Hagemann and De Clerck-Sachsse 2007a, 2007b) to analyze the council voting decisions at the end of negotiations.4 To gather information regarding negotiation positions at the beginning of council deliberations, the analysis of negotiation protocols (Bueno de Mesquita and Stokman 1994; König 1997; Hug and König 2001; Hopmann 2002) or the direct interviewing of negotiation participants has been used (Thomson et al. 2006). Whereas text analysis has the advantages of being easily accessible to other researchers, reliable, and economical (Sullivan and Selck 2007), interviews can shed light on actual negotiations not noted in protocols and help researchers identify the most important negotiation issues and determine the salience of these issues for the individual negotiating parties. The downside, however, is that interviewees might have faulty memories or may be self-serving in their responses, portraying situations to their advantage — the so-called ex post rationalization (Bueno de Mesquita 2004).

Both methods of identifying negotiation positions — text analysis of council votes and deliberations and interviews — may not actually reveal how closely official positions reflect the actual preferences of actors; this applies to the qualitative (Moravcsik 1998; Dinan 1999; Hösli 2000) as well as quantitative studies (Bueno de Mesquita and Stokman 1994; König 1997; Thomson et al. 2006). While Christopher Achen (2006) considers it possible to learn a negotiator’s sincere position, Bruce Bueno de Mesquita (2004) has claimed that it is practically impossible to ascertain his or her true opinion. Indeed, he argued that where there is a low probability of finding out negotiators’ real preferences, especially when information is incomplete, it is far too advantageous for a diplomat to assume a strategic position. If such positions reflect only strategic goals, then negotiation analyses could be seriously biased. Consequently, because analyses of negotiations are based on the preferences of actors (as is the case with many other political science studies), the question of which variables determine their positions is highly relevant and important for developing hypotheses about behavior in international negotiations.

The Data

The primary source of information for this analysis is the data set “Decision Making in the European Union,” which includes detailed information on sixty-six legislative proposals negotiated by the Council of Ministers from 2000 to 2002 (Thomson et al. 2006). This data set was compiled to create a collection of information on day-to-day negotiations in the Council of Ministers, in order to test bargaining models. Therefore, each legislative proposal needed to raise at least a minimum level of controversy in order to be considered. The selection criterion was whether “Agence Europe,” a daily comprehensive news service reporting about EU activities, mentioned a proposal, and subsequently, whether an EU expert confirmed that the proposal was contentious. Finally, the legislative proposals that were selected were either subject to the consultation or the codecision procedure, which both require unanimity, or to a qualified majority, which required sixty-two of the eighty-seven votes in the Council of Ministers.

Interviews were only conducted with experts who had a chance to witness the whole bargaining process, both between and within the diverse legislative bodies of the EU and thus typically included officials from the European Commission, staff from the Council of Ministers, or the Permanent Representations of the Member States in Brussels. In the interviews, the experts were first asked to identify the controversial issues within a proposal. Based on this, they were subsequently asked to indicate the position that the decisive actors (member states, the commission, and the European Parliament) took after the introduction of the proposal before the council formulated its common position. The experts were then asked to locate the two EU actors holding the two most extreme positions on the two endpoints 0 and 100. This was used as a means of representing all the stakeholders’ opinions on the issue, with the intermediate positions taken up by the remaining EU actors seen as representing less extreme positions or compromise solutions. In cases in which qualitative (as opposed to numerical) issues were negotiated, the creators of the data set relied on the interviewees’ expertise to identify the distance between the positions of the negotiating parties. The majority of issues (109 of 162) reflected a ranked ordering of policy positions; thirty-three of the issues were dichotomous, where the only positions were 0 and 100; and in twenty cases the measurement is relatively scalar, indicating that all points on the dimension represent a substantive position (e.g., financial transfers to a certain EU program).

Other interview questions — apart from those that asked for status quo and outcome — pertained to the salience attributed to the contested issues, which we defined as the importance actors attached to the negotiation topic. Salience was measured on a scale between 0 and 100, with 100 indicating that an issue was of highest importance and 50 marking an average priority.

To explain the negotiation positions assumed, I use several independent variables measuring the economic and societal interests of the EU member states, as well as their ideological orientation. All variables and operationalizations used for this analysis are listed in Table One.

Table One

Independent Variables Used for the Analyses in Tables Two to Four 

VariablesMeanStandard DeviationMinMax
Net benefit from EU budget (difference between contribution to and payment from EU budget in million Euros (http://www.destatis.de−717.2 3,974.22 −11,400.00 4,483.00 
Left–right preference of EU governments (1 = left, 20 = right), one value for each cabinet minister, weighted by size of coalition parties (Benoit and Laver 200510.50 2.64 6.29 16.99 
EU integration attitude of EU governments, (1 = favor shifting more authority toward EU authority, 20 = favor reducing authority from EU authority), one value for each cabinet minister, weighted by size of coalition parties (Benoit and Laver 2005). 8.49 1.94 5.16 12.61 
Consumer protectionism: percentage of persons who believe that there is not a high level of consumer protection in other EU countries (Eurobarometer Survey on Consumer Protection, Special Report, 193, November 2003, Question 27) 25.77 5.20 18.00 36.6 
Agricultural workforce: share of employees working in the agricultural sector as percentage of workforce (Eurostat, http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu0.06 0.051 0.018 0.19 
Fisheries workforce: No. of fishers in 1995 (Eurostat) 17,116.85 21,670.91 624.00 75,009.00 
Salience per negotiation issue on a scale from 0 to100 59.07 23.28 100.00 
GNP in 2000 in billions Euro (http://www.destatis.de568.6 642.01 21.00 2,026.00 
Length of legislative procedure for each legislative proposal (0 = less than 900 days, 1 = more than 900 days) 0.159 0.36 1.00 
Codecision procedure (26 of 66 proposals were subject to the codecision procedure) 0.62 0.49 1.00 
QMV: qualified majority voting (45 of 66 proposals were subject to qualified majority voting) 0.69 0.46 1.00 
VariablesMeanStandard DeviationMinMax
Net benefit from EU budget (difference between contribution to and payment from EU budget in million Euros (http://www.destatis.de−717.2 3,974.22 −11,400.00 4,483.00 
Left–right preference of EU governments (1 = left, 20 = right), one value for each cabinet minister, weighted by size of coalition parties (Benoit and Laver 200510.50 2.64 6.29 16.99 
EU integration attitude of EU governments, (1 = favor shifting more authority toward EU authority, 20 = favor reducing authority from EU authority), one value for each cabinet minister, weighted by size of coalition parties (Benoit and Laver 2005). 8.49 1.94 5.16 12.61 
Consumer protectionism: percentage of persons who believe that there is not a high level of consumer protection in other EU countries (Eurobarometer Survey on Consumer Protection, Special Report, 193, November 2003, Question 27) 25.77 5.20 18.00 36.6 
Agricultural workforce: share of employees working in the agricultural sector as percentage of workforce (Eurostat, http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu0.06 0.051 0.018 0.19 
Fisheries workforce: No. of fishers in 1995 (Eurostat) 17,116.85 21,670.91 624.00 75,009.00 
Salience per negotiation issue on a scale from 0 to100 59.07 23.28 100.00 
GNP in 2000 in billions Euro (http://www.destatis.de568.6 642.01 21.00 2,026.00 
Length of legislative procedure for each legislative proposal (0 = less than 900 days, 1 = more than 900 days) 0.159 0.36 1.00 
Codecision procedure (26 of 66 proposals were subject to the codecision procedure) 0.62 0.49 1.00 
QMV: qualified majority voting (45 of 66 proposals were subject to qualified majority voting) 0.69 0.46 1.00 

EU, European Union; GNP, gross national product.

The financial benefit that EU states derive from the EU is measured by the difference between their contribution to and payment received from the EU budget, the net benefit from the EU, the data for which are drawn from the relevant statistics of Eurostat (http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu). The economic interests in the fields of agriculture and fisheries are measured on the basis of the agricultural and fishery workforce in the respective countries.

To measure domestic constraints, I used the attitude of the population toward consumer protection in the EU, as is noted in the Eurobarometer surveys of the EU. To test for attitudes toward the EU and the left–right positions of EU governments, I used the expert survey data from a data set created by Kenneth Benoit and Michael Laver (2005), in which experts gathered the positions of parties on the left–right scale (1 = left, 20 = right) and on the question of whether they favored shifting more authority toward the EU (= 1) or away from it (= 20). Each government represented in the Council of Ministers at the time when the commission initiated one of the sixty proposals is thus assigned a value for its left–right position and EU friendliness. For coalition governments, for example, Germany, I weighed the values according to the size of coalition parties operationalized by the number of ministers in a coalition government.

In this section, I present two methods of analysis for examining the preferences of EU governments. In both, I investigate which variables explain the negotiation positions of member states in the EU Council of Ministers negotiations. For this purpose, I use negotiation issues from just three policy areas — financial, consumer, and institutional policy — in the first analysis. In the second analysis, I consider the latent variables that underlie the negotiation issues as the dependent variable to achieve the same goal, explaining the position of member states in negotiations.

In my first analysis, I identify nine issues from the DEU data set that deal with various types of subsidies and payments, that is, financial issues, as the first dimension. The dependent variable here is the position of an EU government on these issues on a scale from 0 to 100, where a higher scalar position corresponds to spending more money. The issues range from financing measures promoting the European audiovisual industry to the budget of the civil protection program to the amount of money allocated for the seven-year Socrates program supporting educational programs. The two other dimensions, consumer issues and institutional issues, are also scaled so that a higher position on the scale reflects more consumer protection and more EU integration, respectively. Table Two displays the results of the multivariate analyses in which I use a fixed-effects regression analysis technique to control for omitted variables that differ between the issues but are constant over time. This is equivalent to using dummy variables for each of the issues.5

Table Two

Multivariate Analysis of the Choice of Positions on Negotiation Issues in Three Policy Areas

Financial IssuesConsumer IssuesInstitutional Issuesa
Net benefit from EU budget 0.01***  0.05***      
 (0.00)  (0.00)      
Left–right preference of EU governments  0.09 −1.99**  −0.46 −0.48  −0.44* 
  (0.93) (0.83)  (0.6) (0.67)  (1.23) 
Attitude to consumer protection    0.04  0.50   
    (0.12)  (0.12)   
EU integration attitude of EU governments       −3.40**  
       (1.55)  
Constant 63.46*** 57.98*** 84.13*** 48.76*** 56.01*** 53.67*** 84.71*** 56.24*** 
 (2.22) (11.12) (8.88) (5.88) (7.29) (8.92) (13.53) (13.05) 
F 62.33*** 0.01 35.25*** 0.18 0.49 0.35 0.48 0.13 
Observations 133 133 133 377 377 377 97 97 
Overall R2 0.27 0.00 0.30 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.05 0.01 
Financial IssuesConsumer IssuesInstitutional Issuesa
Net benefit from EU budget 0.01***  0.05***      
 (0.00)  (0.00)      
Left–right preference of EU governments  0.09 −1.99**  −0.46 −0.48  −0.44* 
  (0.93) (0.83)  (0.6) (0.67)  (1.23) 
Attitude to consumer protection    0.04  0.50   
    (0.12)  (0.12)   
EU integration attitude of EU governments       −3.40**  
       (1.55)  
Constant 63.46*** 57.98*** 84.13*** 48.76*** 56.01*** 53.67*** 84.71*** 56.24*** 
 (2.22) (11.12) (8.88) (5.88) (7.29) (8.92) (13.53) (13.05) 
F 62.33*** 0.01 35.25*** 0.18 0.49 0.35 0.48 0.13 
Observations 133 133 133 377 377 377 97 97 
Overall R2 0.27 0.00 0.30 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.05 0.01 

Note: The list of issues used for this table is provided in the  Appendix. Standard errors are in parentheses. *Significant at 100%; significant at 5%; significant at 1%.

a

These results were obtained using a model based on robust standard errors clustered at the issue level instead of a fixed-effects model to account for outliers. In the fixed-effects model, the coefficients had the same direction but were not significant.

EU, European Union.

In the first column of Table Two, we see that governments’ utilitarian financial considerations allow for the prediction of their positions in the negotiations: the independent variable “net benefit from EU,” which measures the profit of an EU member from the EU budget, has a significant and positive coefficient, suggesting that the more a state has benefited from the EU budget, the more likely it is to spend money on EU policies. Disregarding all other aspects of these negotiation issues (culture, fisheries, etc.), the net variable explains 27 percent of the variance on financial issues.

The variable that controls for the partisan preferences of the EU governments, “Left–right preference of EU governments,” is, however, not significant when tested for its influence on the positions regarding financial issues, unless the financial interests of the EU member states are also accounted for, as I did in column three of the model, where the effect does become significant. Here, the negative coefficient indicates that right-wing governments favor lower EU expenditure than the more left-wing-oriented governments. This is another confirmation of the results of Douglas Hibbs’ (1977) famous study on the influence of parties on public spending in which he found that left-wing governments favor higher state spending.

Regarding the preferences of the EU governments on issues concerning consumer protection, such as the labeling of honey or the strength of a health warning, I could not find a variable that compellingly explains the choice of position. Neither the “Attitude to consumer protection” (operationalized as the percentage of people in a country who think that the level of consumer protection in their own country is high, as measured in Eurobarometer surveys) nor various other variables, such as the post-materialism index (an index compiled of survey answers measuring to which degree postmaterialist values are held in the sample of various populations) created by Ronald Inglehart and Christian Welzel (2005), can explain the positions of the EU governments regarding the labeling of products. Although the variable points in the expected positive direction — indicating that states whose citizens favor stronger consumer protectionism are much more likely to promote stricter consumer laws at the EU level — it is not significant according to conventional standards.

Similarly, the partisan variable is negative as expected, suggesting that right-wing governments are less inclined to support consumer protection than left-wing governments, but fails to reach significance at the conventional level. These results might however be caused by the twentry-seven relatively diverse issues investigated. Indeed, it is quite possible that additional considerations, for example, those related to the agriculture, tobacco, and medical products sectors, are not captured very well by the rather crude measurement of average levels of consumer protectionism in a country.

In the third model, which investigates how we can explain the choice of negotiation positions in institutional negotiation issues, we see that the variable measuring the attitude of EU governments toward EU integration is significant. It indicates that the more skeptical a government is of the EU, the closer to zero it is located on the institutional issue scale. These states seek to guard their rights in interinstitutional disputes concerning, for example, conflicts about the appropriate voting mechanism in the EU implementation (comitology) commissions or debates about the degree of autonomy given to the European Commission. The partisan preference variable indicates that parties further to the right tend to be more careful about shifting rights toward the EU. This confirms Simon Hix’s (2005) findings, which state that in some EU member states, the left is more pro-European than the right.6

In sum, I have demonstrated in this first analysis that financial interests and attitudes toward European integration can to some extent explain the positions that EU governments are likely to take in EU negotiations. Controlling for partisan preferences did in two instances help to increase the explanatory power of the models to a small extent. As the F-tests indicate, however, the overall significance of the models is limited; also, some of the coefficients are rather small because many specificities of the individual negotiation issues might not be well captured. Consequently, I have undertaken a second analysis of negotiation dimensions.

My second analysis of the determinants of negotiation positions is based upon data generated by Zimmer, Schneider, and Dobbins (2005), who investigated the underlying dimensions of the 150 negotiation issues in the DEU data set. With a correspondence analysis of council negotiation positions, Zimmer and her coauthors showed that the dominant dimension in the council negotiations was a north–south divide, caused by the states’ differing interests in market regulation, protectionism, and financial contributions to the EU.7 Also, by splitting the negotiation issues into the policy domains of internal market and agriculture, they argued that their calculated latent policy dimensions cover between 66 and 86 percent of the variance of positions (Zimmer, Schneider, and Dobbins 2005: 412).8

Using correspondence analysis to reduce the issues to these key latent dimensions offers several advantages in contrast to the direct analysis of positions on the actual issues: first, interviewer effects (the discrepancies caused by different interview partners) have a much smaller weight if the dimensions are reduced to a few latent ones. Second, situational effects stemming from particular negotiation situations, such the details of certain policy issues, matter less (Bradburn and Sudman 1979). Thus, this second analysis can show whether my findings from the first analysis also hold for the discussion of latent dimensions and not only for the purely political dimensions, as in Table One. Furthermore, additional policy areas — internal market, agriculture and fishery policy — are also investigated in the second analysis.

Table Three shows the results of my multivariate analyses using ordinary least squares (OLS) regression and addresses the positions of EU member states in the policy sectors internal market, agriculture, and fisheries, using the structural, domestic, and partisan variables. In the first model, I again use the variable “Net benefit from EU budget” to explain the first dimension of positions in internal market negotiations. The reasoning behind this test is the assumption that states receiving a greater share of the EU budget have a different interest in EU internal market issues than other states do. The significant and negative coefficient of the budget variable means that countries benefiting financially from the EU prefer to be located on the low end of the scale of the first latent internal market dimension. The second model refers to the impact of the left–right orientation of EU governments on this dimension and shows that more right-wing EU states are usually located at the other end of the scale. (I refrained from testing the two variables in one model because of the small number of cases.)

Table Three

Analysis of the Choice of Negotiation Positions on the Latent Policy Dimensions

1. Dimension Internal Market “Market Regulation”2. Dimension Internal Market “Consumer Protection — Producer Interests”1. Dimension Agriculture “Agricultural Subsidies”1. Dimension Fisheries “Fishery Subsidies”
Structural ModelPartisan ModelStructural ModelPartisan ModelStructural ModelPartisan ModelStructural ModelPartisan Model
Net benefit from EU budget −0.0001***        
(0.00)        
Left–right preference of EU governments  0.35*  −0.13  0.07  0.06 
 0.18  (0.09)  (0.14)  (0.09) 
Consumer protectionism   0.12***      
  (0.04)      
Agricultural workforce     19.36***    
    (5.21)    
Fisheries workforce       0.00**  
      (0.00)  
Constant −0.12 −3.46 −3.22***  −1.21 −0.78 −0.27 −0.68 
(0.34) (1.87) (1.04)  (0.42) (1.55) (0.00) (0.94) 
F 3.58* 0.08 9.97*** 1.88 13.81*** 0.27 6.55** 0.55 
n 15 14 15 15 15 15 13 15 
Adjusted R2 0.16 0.18 0.39 0.05 0.47 −0.05 0.31 −0.03 
1. Dimension Internal Market “Market Regulation”2. Dimension Internal Market “Consumer Protection — Producer Interests”1. Dimension Agriculture “Agricultural Subsidies”1. Dimension Fisheries “Fishery Subsidies”
Structural ModelPartisan ModelStructural ModelPartisan ModelStructural ModelPartisan ModelStructural ModelPartisan Model
Net benefit from EU budget −0.0001***        
(0.00)        
Left–right preference of EU governments  0.35*  −0.13  0.07  0.06 
 0.18  (0.09)  (0.14)  (0.09) 
Consumer protectionism   0.12***      
  (0.04)      
Agricultural workforce     19.36***    
    (5.21)    
Fisheries workforce       0.00**  
      (0.00)  
Constant −0.12 −3.46 −3.22***  −1.21 −0.78 −0.27 −0.68 
(0.34) (1.87) (1.04)  (0.42) (1.55) (0.00) (0.94) 
F 3.58* 0.08 9.97*** 1.88 13.81*** 0.27 6.55** 0.55 
n 15 14 15 15 15 15 13 15 
Adjusted R2 0.16 0.18 0.39 0.05 0.47 −0.05 0.31 −0.03 

Note: The second model is calculated using robust regression, which excluded one strong outlying case; therefore, the number of cases is only fourteen. Standard errors are in parentheses; *significant at 10%; **significant at 5%; ***significant at 1%.

EU, European Union.

By identifying the topics that bear most decisively upon these dimensions, Zimmer, Schneider, and Dobbins (2005) defined the second dimension of the internal market as one that is dominated by consumer protection and producer interests (columns 3 and 4 of Table Three). To test for consumer protectionism, I used the percentage of people who are of the opinion that there is a lower level of consumer protection in other EU countries, using this to measure the “missionary behavior” of citizens who believe that other EU countries are not as advanced as their own country regarding consumer issues. Such behavior can be observed, for example, in internal market negotiations in which countries with high consumer protection standards (such as Denmark and Sweden, which are at one end of this scale) try to impose their ideas on countries with fewer restrictions (such as the United Kingdom or Ireland, which are located at the opposite end of the scale). This can alternatively be interpreted as a “strategy of raising rival’s costs” (Vaubel 2006: 132), which more highly regulated member states may use to raise the costs of others by imposing their own level of regulation on them. Although only an approximate measure of consumer protection, it actually explains a strikingly large percentage (39 percent) of the variance on this second dimension of internal market negotiation positions.

To operationalize producer interests as a counterpoint to those of consumers, I evaluated the effect of a country’s industrial production upon each of the positions. Both variables fail to show a significant effect.9 This could indicate that the measurements do not capture producer interests precisely enough; indeed, these are relatively difficult to measure as such interests are very heterogeneous and thus too widespread to be implemented in such an analysis. The partisan preference of the EU governments had a negative effect as expected, indicating that right-wing governments tend to assume positions on the opposite side of the scale as consumer protectionists; however, the variable is not significant by conventional standards.

Domestic as well as structural interests are visible in the explanation of negotiation positions in another crucial policy area of the EU — agricultural policy. Here, the share of people employed in the agricultural sector explains why actors are located on the upper end of the scale of this dimension (column 5 of Table Three); indeed, the larger the workforce employed in the agricultural sector, the further up the scale the country is located on the first agricultural dimension. Interestingly, this relatively crude measure of a state’s interest in the domain of agriculture alone seems to account for a large degree of the variance on this particular dimension. But when I control for partisan preferences, this variable turns out to lack significance. Nonetheless, the positive coefficient illustrates that right-wing governments often enact more farmer-friendly policies and are therefore on the same side of the political dimension as the agricultural sector, which confirms the usual coalition between conservative parties and the agricultural sector. The partisan orientation, however, has a smaller coefficient than does the economic interest of the agricultural workforce.

I obtained comparable results in the area of fishery policy: here, I use the number of fishermen in EU countries, which accounts to some degree (31 percent) for the positions of the governments in discussions pertaining to this policy area, although the coefficient is admittedly quite small. As was true in the case of agricultural and consumer issues in the bivariate models in Table Three, a distinctly smaller percentage of the variance is explained by partisan preferences than by structural and domestic interests. These analyses thus indicate that a country whose employment force is highly dependent on the fishery sector will behave in a predictable way in fisheries negotiations, regardless of whether it has a right-wing or left-wing government.

Looking at the F-tests of the various models, which are significant only for the structural models but not for the partisan models, these analyses illustrate that a large percentage of the positions of EU delegations are an expression of their structural and social interests, confirming that the DEU data actually reflect sincere positions of EU actors, rather than purely strategic ones — a claim made by the DEU research group (Thomson et al. 2006).

The remaining unexplained variance could have several explanations. First, states could have further interests that were not controlled for; this is likely because I used relatively crude measures in the absence of more direct ones. Second, the unexplained variance could be because of measurement errors in the interviews. Third, I must also consider the possibility that there may still be some aspect of strategy included in the choice of a position. Indeed, it is possible that — in spite of the frequency of meetings — the negotiation delegations assume strategic positions that cannot be directly explicated through structural or social interests, which might be particularly germane to cases in which especially important topics are discussed. As noted above, extreme positions at the beginning of a bargaining round can be a popular method for negotiators to demonstrate their determination to the other participants. Therefore, I have analyzed whether an extreme position can be explainedon the basis of strategic considerations. (This analysis also serves as a robustness check of the data.)

Using an OLS regression, shown in Table Four, I investigate which of the independent variables salience and power, introduced in Hypotheses Three and Four, can explain the choice of an extreme position in Council of Ministers negotiations. The measure for an extreme position is the distance of each member state’s opinion from the opinion median of all member states per negotiation issue, the opinion median being the outcome that would result if the negotiators did not bargain (Black 1948). This measure is calculated for the fifteen EU member states on 150 negotiation issues in the DEU data (n = 2,245).10 For control variables, I use again the partisan orientation of the EU governments, and dummies for the use of the codecision procedure (which involves the European Parliament), qualified majority voting, and the length of a proposal. The variable “Length of proposal” is designated by a 1 if the proposal was debated for more than 900 days and therefore belongs to the top 15 percent of proposals in terms of length. I include this measure to see whether extreme positions were lengthily debated and were thus probably more contested proposals.

Table Four

OLS Regression on Extreme Negotiation Positions

Distance to the Opinion Median of the Member States per Negotiation Issue (Robust Standard Errors in Parentheses)
Salience 0.24***/(0.05) 
GNP 0.004***/(0.001) 
Left–right orientation of government 0.58***/(0.18) 
Length of proc. 5.37*/(2.91) 
Codecision 0.49/(2.25) 
QMV 6.83***(2.42) 
Constant −7.42*(4.12) 
F 12.39*** 
n 2,245 
R2 0.06 
Distance to the Opinion Median of the Member States per Negotiation Issue (Robust Standard Errors in Parentheses)
Salience 0.24***/(0.05) 
GNP 0.004***/(0.001) 
Left–right orientation of government 0.58***/(0.18) 
Length of proc. 5.37*/(2.91) 
Codecision 0.49/(2.25) 
QMV 6.83***(2.42) 
Constant −7.42*(4.12) 
F 12.39*** 
n 2,245 
R2 0.06 

***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1.

GNP, gross national product; QMV, qualified majority voting.

From the results in Table Four, we can see that, as expected, extreme positions are assumed when governments care very much about an issue or when they are powerful; indeed, as anticipated in Hypothesis Three, strong interest in a certain negotiation issue motivates governments to choose a position further from the median, indicated by the positive and highly significant coefficient of the salience variable. This confirms negotiation research that has shown that bold strategies are worth the effort because higher aspirations lead to higher payoffs (Zetik and Stuhlmacher 2002; Wolfe and McGinn 2005).

As noted, the analysis also indicates, on the basis of the positive and significant coefficient, that the strategy of commencing a negotiation with a more extreme position is chosen especially by economically powerful EU states. Here, the economic size of EU member states can also be considered as an alternative measure for concern or overall salience of issues, because the economically powerful states have more diverse interests to represent and have thus an overall average salience. This result also shows that, in contrast to some negotiation theories that point out that high aspirations lead to more bargaining success independent of the resources of an actor (Wolfe and McGinn 2005), the delegations in the EU seem to follow the pattern that the large member states — which can afford to be extreme because they can get away with this behavior — end up choosing extreme positions. When I control for the partisan orientation of governments, I find that right-wing governments tend to assume more extreme positions than left-wing-oriented governments as the positive and highly significant coefficient indicates.

In addition, the analysis shows that the choice of position is also influenced by the characteristics of the negotiation topic. The dummy variable controlling for the length of a legislative negotiation indicates that extreme positions are especially likely in negotiations that extend for several years.

As mentioned, I control for the institutional effects of the legislative procedure using two dummy variables, one for the codecision procedure and the other for the existence of majority voting. Theoretically, I would have expected that extreme positions are assumed in cases of unanimity voting, because these are the situations where an actor can turn into a veto player and block a compromise; on the other hand, taking on an extreme position in qualified majority voting situations is theoretically useless because the majority can simply ignore the veto player (Tsebelis 2002). But the significant coefficient of the qualified majority voting dummy could indicate that negotiations in the council are governed by different forms of behavior: even in negotiations in which an outlier could be ignored, actors seem to adopt these positions to signal that they have an increased interest in a negotiation issue and are thus keen to get concessions from the other participants.

Such behavior is reported to be efficient in negotiations when governments overplay their domestic constraints in the sense of the “paradox of weakness,” in order to obtain concessions (Schelling 1960; Putnam 1988; Schneider, Finke, and Bailer 2010). I analyze the positions stated at the beginning of negotiations, however, and it seems likely that extreme positions are abandoned during the course of negotiations so that a compromise with the necessary majority can be found.

The positive coefficient of the codecision procedure suggests that negotiators use the extreme-position strategy especially when they face the more complicated legislative procedure that involves the European Parliament. This coefficient, however, is not significant by conventional standards.

The analysis of extreme positions also serves as a robustness check for my previous analyses. The results concerning the degree of influence achieved by actors taking extreme positions suggest that some negotiation situations are more likely to attract such extreme negotiation behavior. Moreover, these results confirm the earlier findings that indicated a high degree of sincerity in the positions in regular Council of Ministers negotiations. It is quite possible that extreme positions are sometimes chosen in exceptionally salient situations; however, compromise- and result-oriented negotiations in the council appear to be more typical.

In this study, I have demonstrated that negotiation positions in the EU Council of Ministers are most often a reflection of the structural and domestic interests of states. The partisan orientation of governments influences the choice in some instances but less distinctly so. Therefore, knowing the interests of relevant domestic stakeholders might reveal more about the negotiation position of an EU member state than knowing which party is represented in government. After examining the determinants of negotiation positions, I have also investigated whether the negotiation positions collected in the DEU data set are sincere positions. For frequent negotiations in particular — as in the Council of Ministers — positions stated at the beginning of bargaining rounds to a large extent reflect states’ sincere interests and are rarely designed to bluff and hide an actual position.

Nevertheless, I also found evidence of extreme positions being used, at least to some degree, in contested negotiations. Such findings provide a modicum of support for the idea that such a position can reflect strategic and tactical considerations. It is especially when governments care a lot about a certain negotiation issue that they choose extreme positions; furthermore, this strategy is more often chosen by powerful states, possibly because the smaller ones, knowing that they do not stand many chances of winning with such a risky strategy, might choose not to risk such a failure.

The higher frequency of council negotiations, however, in contrast to EU summit negotiations, leads to less use of these kinds of insincere strategies. Here, the “shadow of the future” (Axelrod 1984), the idea that it pays to cooperate when you will interact repeatedly with the same party, ensures that government’s representatives in council negotiations cannot use bluffing and other similarly bold strategies carelessly. Therefore, I assert that both insincere strategic and sincere considerations determine the course of day-to-day legislative negotiations in the EU. Dramatic strategic moves are reserved for exceptional bargains, whereas the daily business of negotiating EU legislation is determined by the sincere structural and societal interests of the governments. It is extremely challenging to conclude, however, whether states are behaving strategically or sincerely by looking only at their negotiation positions and behavior.

Future research could investigate situations in which governments represent domestic interests that are not easily compatible with their ideological and party orientations, for example, when a Social Democratic chancellor defends industrial interests at the expense of the environment and consumers. Future research should examine in more detail who prevails in which situations: the stakeholders or the party ideology. Presumably the salience of negotiation issues — who cares most about and “owns” the issue — and the type of negotiation — whether it is redistributive or regulatory and whether the effect can be directly perceived by stakeholders, as in the case of job losses — are factors that influence these effects, also. Thus, comparative negotiation research interlinking the insights of comparative politics with research on negotiation positions and international politics could further illuminate the negotiation behavior of states.

I thank Thilo Bodenstein, Gerald Schneider, Peter Selb, the reviewers of this journal, and Nancy Waters for very helpful and constructive comments.

1

Studies of EU negotiations must distinguish between negotiations in the European Council (“EU summits”) and the Council of the EU (also known as the Council of Ministers). These two types of negotiation rounds differ in the frequency of meetings, the actors involved, the negotiation issues, and the decision-making mechanisms. In European Council meetings, heads of states negotiate the “general political guidelines” of the EU approximately four times a year, while the negotiations in the Council of Ministers play out over various discussion rounds from the working groups via the Coreper to the actual Council of Ministers rounds (Hayes-Renshaw and Wallace 2006). While the European Council meetings are dominated by general discussions about policy guidelines, the degree of technicality of negotiation issues is necessarily lower than in the Council of Ministers, where actual legislation is debated by civil servants, diplomats, and ministers (Bailer 2010).

3

COM (1996) 97 Proposal for a European Parliament and Council Directive on the resale right for the benefit of the author of an original work of art.

4

The data on voting records in the Council of Ministers are available online at: http://www.councildata.cergu.gu.se/

5

I also controlled for possible dependencies between the observations in the regression analyses because the position of one actor could be dependent on the position of another actor. The results do not vary significantly from those displayed in Table Two.

6

I could not test the partisan and integration variables in one model because they are highly correlated (Pearson correlation coefficient = 0.8), and would thus have caused multicollinearity when used in the same model.

7

They identify the meaning of the dimensions by looking at the meaning of the issues with the highest loading factors on the calculated dimensions.

8

I am grateful to Christina Zimmer for making these data available to me.

9

Analysis not shown here but available from the author upon request.

10

I use the cluster option in Stata for this analysis to account for the fact that the issues are not independent from each other, as well as robust standard errors.

Achen
,
C. H.
2006
.
Evaluating political decision making models
. In
The European Union decides: Political economy of institutions and decisions
, edited by
R.
Thomson
,
F. N.
Stokman
,
C. H.
Achen
, and
T.
König
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
.
Axelrod
,
R.
1984
.
The evolution of cooperation
.
New York
:
Basic Books
.
Bailer
,
S.
2004
.
Bargaining success in the European Union
.
European Union Politics
.
5
(
1
):
99
123
.
Bailer
,
S.
2010
.
What factors determine bargaining power in the EU?
Journal of European Public Policy
.
17
(
5
):
743
752
.
Bechtel
,
M. M.
and
G.
Schneider
.
2010
.
Eliciting substance from “hot air”: Financial market responses to EU summit decisions on European defense
.
International Organization
.
64
(
2
):
199
223
.
Benoit
,
K.
and
M.
Laver
.
2005
.
Party policy in modern democracies
.
London
:
Routledge
.
Black
,
D.
1948
.
On the rationale of group decision-making
.
Journal of Political Economy
.
56
(
1
):
23
34
.
Bradburn
,
N. M.
and
S.
Sudman
.
1979
.
Improving interview method and questionnaire design. Response effects to threatening questions in survey research
.
San Francisco, CA
:
Jossey-Bass
.
Bräuninger
,
T.
2001
.
Nationale Interessen und internationale Verhandlungen. Determinanten von Staatenpositionen in der internationalen Politik. Konstanz
.
Konstanz
:
Universität
.
Bueno de Mesquita
,
B.
2004
.
Decision making models, rigor, and new puzzles
.
European Union Politics
.
5
(
1
):
125
138
.
Bueno de Mesquita
,
B.
and
F. N.
Stokman
.
1994
.
European community decision making
.
New Haven, CT
:
Yale University Press
.
Dinan
,
D.
1999
.
Ever closer union. An introduction to European integration
, 2nd edn.
Boulder, CO
:
Lynne Rienner Publishers
.
Elgström
,
O.
,
B.
Bjurulf
,
J.
Johansson
, and
A.
Sannerstedt
.
2002
.
Coalitions in European Union negotiations
.
Scandinavian Political Studies
.
24
(
2
):
111
128
.
European Union Council of Ministers
.
1995
: COM(1995)655 Proposal for a 13th European Parliament and Council directive on company law concerning takeover bids.
European Union Council of Ministers
.
1996
: COM(1996)97 Proposal for a European Parliament and Council directive on the resale right for the benefit of the author of an original work of art.
European Union Council of Ministers
.
1997
: COM(1997)358 Proposal for a Council directive on end of life vehicles.
Fisher
,
R.
,
W.
Ury
, and
B.
Patton
.
1991
.
Negotiation power: Ingredients in an ability to influence the other side
. In
Negotiation. Strategies for mutual gain. The basic seminar of the Harvard Program on Negotiation
, edited by
L.
Hall
and
N.
Park
.
London
:
Sage Publications
.
Frieden
,
J.
1999
.
Actors and preferences in international relations
. In
Strategic choice and international relations
, edited by
D. A.
Lake
and
R.
Powell
.
Princeton, NJ
:
Princeton University Press
.
Gabel
,
M.
,
S.
Hix
, and
G.
Schneider
.
2002
.
Who is afraid of cumulative research? The scarcity of EU decision making data and what can be done about this
.
European Union Politics
.
3
(
4
):
481
500
.
Gibbons
,
R.
1997
.
An introduction to applicable game theory
.
Journal of Economic Perspectives
.
11
(
1
):
127
149
.
Hagemann
,
S.
2007
.
Applying ideal point estimation to the Council of Ministers
.
European Union Politics
.
8
(
2
):
279
296
.
Hagemann
,
S.
and
J.
De Clerck-Sachsse
.
2007a
.
Decision-making in the enlarged Council of Ministers: Evaluating the facts. CEPS Policy Brief
, No. 119. Available from http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1349087.
Hagemann
,
S.
and
J.
De Clerck-Sachsse
.
2007b
.
Old rules, new game. Decision-making in the Council of Ministers after the 2004 enlargement
.
Centre for Economic Policy Studies, Special Report
.
March
.
Hagemann
,
S.
and
B.
Hoyland
.
2008
.
Parties in the Council?
Journal of European Public Policy
.
15
(
8
):
1205
1221
.
Hayes-Renshaw
,
F.
,
W.
Van Aken
, and
H.
Wallace
.
2006
.
When and why the EU Council of Ministers votes explicitly
.
Journal of Common Market Studies
.
44
(
1
):
161
194
.
Hayes-Renshaw
,
F.
and
H.
Wallace
.
2006
.
The Council of Ministers
, 2nd edn.
London
:
Palgrave Macmillan
.
Hibbs
,
D. A.
Jr.
.
1977
.
Political parties and macroeconomic policy
.
American Political Science Review
.
71
(
4
):
1467
1487
.
Hix
,
S.
2005
.
The political system of the European Union
, 2nd edn.
London
:
Palgrave
.
Hix
,
S.
and
A.
Noury
.
2006
.
After enlargement: Voting patterns in the Sixth European Parliament
. Paper presented at The European Parliament and the European Political Space,
London
,
March 30
.
Hopmann
,
P. T.
2002
.
Negotiating data: Reflections on the qualitative and quantitative analysis of negotiation processes
.
International Negotiation
.
7
:
67
85
.
Hösli
,
M. O.
2000
.
The creation of the European economic and monetary union (EMU): Intergovernmental negotiations and two-level games
.
Journal of European Public Policy
.
7
(
5
):
744
766
.
Hovi
,
J.
1998
.
Games, threats and treaties
.
London
:
Pinter
.
Hug
,
S.
2003
.
Endogenous preferences and delegation in the European Union
.
Comparative Political Studies
.
36
(
1/2
):
41
74
.
Hug
,
S.
and
T.
König
.
2001
.
In view of ratification. Governmental preferences and domestic constraints at the Amsterdam Intergovernmental Conference
.
International Organization
.
56
(
2
):
447
476
.
Inglehart
,
R.
and
C.
Welzel
.
2005
.
Modernization, cultural change, and democracy. The human development sequence
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
.
Jensen
,
C. B.
and
J. J.
Spoon
.
2011
.
Testing the “party matters” thesis: Explaining progress towards Kyoto Protocol targets
.
Political Studies
.
59
:
99
115
.
Kaeding
,
M.
and
T.
Selck
.
2005
.
Mapping out political Europe: Coalition patterns in EU decision-making
.
International Political Science Review
.
26
(
3
):
271
290
.
Keohane
,
R. O.
and
J.
Nye
.
1989
.
Power and interdependence
, 2nd edn.
Boston, MA
:
Little, Brown
.
König
,
T.
1997
.
Europa auf dem Weg zum Mehrheitssystem. Gründe und Konsequenzen nationaler und parlamentarischer Integration
.
Opladen
:
Westdeutscher Verlag
.
Manow
,
P.
,
A.
Schäfer
, and
H.
Zorn
.
2008
.
Europe’s party-political center of gravity, 1957–2002
.
Journal of European Public Policy
.
15
(
1
):
20
39
.
Mattila
,
M.
2004
.
Contested decisions. Empirical analysis of voting in the EU Council of Ministers
.
European Journal of Political Research
.
43
(
1
):
29
50
.
Mattila
,
M.
2006
.
Voting and coalitions in the Council. Two years after enlargement
. Paper presented at workshop: Who governs in the Council of Ministers?
European University Institute
,
May 19–20
.
Mattila
,
M.
2007
.
The effects of enlargement on council voting and coalitions
. Paper presented at 4th ECPR General Conference,
Pisa
,
September 6–8
.
Mattila
,
M.
2009
.
Roll call analysis of voting in the European Union Council of Ministers after the 2004 enlargement
.
European Journal of Political Research
.
48
(
6
):
840
857
.
Mattila
,
M.
and
J.-E.
Lane
.
2001
.
Why unanimity in the council? A roll call analysis of council voting
.
European Union Politics
.
2
(
1
):
31
52
.
Moravcsik
,
A.
1997
.
Taking preferences seriously: A liberal theory of international politics
.
International Organization
.
51
(
4
):
513
553
.
Moravcsik
,
A.
1998
.
The choice for Europe
.
Ithaca
:
Cornell University Press
.
Morgenthau
,
H. J.
1967
.
Politics among nations. The struggle for power and peace
, 4th edn.
New York
:
Alfred A. Knopf
.
Morrow
,
J. D.
1994
.
Game theory for political scientists
.
Princeton, NJ
:
Princeton University Press
.
Morrow
,
J. D.
1999
.
The strategic setting of choices: Signaling, commitment, and negotiation in international politics
. In
Strategic choice and international relations
, edited by
D. A.
Lake
and
R.
Powell
.
Princeton, NJ
:
Princeton University Press
.
Naurin
,
D.
and
R.
Lindahl
.
2008
.
East–North–South: Coalition-building in the Council before and after enlargement
. In
Unveiling the Council of the European Union. Games governments play in Brussels
, edited by
D.
Naurin
and
H.
Wallace
.
Houndmills Basingstoke
:
Palgrave
.
Putnam
,
R. D.
1988
.
Diplomacy and domestic politics: The logic of two-level games
.
International Organization
.
42
(
3
):
427
460
.
Rubin
,
J. Z.
and
B. R.
Brown
.
1975
.
The social psychology of bargaining and negotiation
.
New York; San Francisco; London
:
Academic Press
.
Schelling
,
T. C.
1960
.
The strategy of conflict
.
Cambridge
:
Harvard University Press
.
Schmidt
,
M. G.
1996
.
When parties matter: A review of the possibilities and limits of partisan influence on public policy
.
European Journal of Political Research
.
30
:
155
183
.
Schneider
,
G.
and
L.-E.
Cederman
.
1994
.
The change of tide in political cooperation: A limited information model of European integration
.
International Organization
.
48
(
4
):
633
662
.
Schneider
,
G.
,
D.
Finke
, and
S.
Bailer
.
2010
.
Bargaining power in the European Union: An evaluation of competing game-theoretic models
.
Political Studies
.
58
(
1
):
85
103
.
Spence
,
M.
1973
.
Job market signaling
.
Quarterly Journal of Economics
.
87
(
3
):
355
374
.
Sullivan
,
J.
and
T.
Selck
.
2007
.
Political preferences, revealed positions and strategic votes: Explaining decision-making in the EU Council
.
Journal of European Public Policy
.
14
(
7
):
1150
1161
.
Thomson
,
R.
,
J.
Boerefijn
, and
F. N.
Stokman
.
2004
.
Actor alignments in European Union decision making
.
European Journal of Political Research
.
43
:
237
261
.
Thomson
,
R.
,
F. N.
Stokman
,
C.
Achen
, and
T.
König
(eds).
2006
.
The European Union decides: Political economy of institutions and decisions
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
.
Tsebelis
,
G.
2002
.
Veto players. How political institutions work
.
Princeton, NJ
:
Princeton University Press
.
Vaubel
,
R.
2006
.
Principal-agent problems in international organizations
.
Review of International Organizations
.
1
(
1
):
125
138
.
Wolfe
,
R. J.
and
K. L.
McGinn
.
2005
.
Perceived, relative power and its influence on negotiations
.
Group Decision and Negotiation
.
14
(
1
):
3
20
.
Zetik
,
D. C.
and
A. F.
Stuhlmacher
.
2002
.
Goal setting and negotiation performance: A meta-analysis
.
Group Processes Intergroup Relations
.
5
(
1
):
35
52
.
Zimmer
,
C.
,
G.
Schneider
, and
M.
Dobbins
.
2005
.
The contested council: Conflict dimensions of intergovernmental institution
.
Political Studies
.
53
(
2
):
403
422
.

Appendix

Issues Analyzed in Table Two 

Document No. and DEU Data Set Issue No.Issues
List of Financial Issues Analyzed in Table Two  
i98329/1 How large should the amount of money allocated to the seven-year Socrates (education) program be? 
i98768/1 How large should the civil protection program budget be every year? 
i99111/1 How high should the percentage of the budget of the European audiovisual observatory be that must be paid with EU funds? 
i99364/1 Which mechanism will be initiated if the year’s agricultural budget is overspent? 
i99382/1 How extensively should a fishery advisory council be financed by the EU and by the member states? 
i99494/2 How large should the budget be that is assigned by the European Commission for financial and technical assistance to Mediterranean countries between 2000 and 2006? 
i996581/1 How large should the amount of money for training measures for people working in the European audiovisual industry 2001–2005 be? 
i996582/1 How much money should be allocated to the development, distribution, and promotion of these audiovisual trainings? 
i996582/5 How much money should be allocated to the pilot studies in the area of vocational training in the European audiovisual industry? 
List of Consumer Issues Analyzed in Table Two  
i00855/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the use and labeling of mixtures of olive oil and vegetable oil? 
i00855/5 What are the preferences of the member states on the labeling of olive oil regarding the country of processing? 
i95520/1 What are the preferences of the member states on the party (consumer or producer) that should take the decision on whether a defective product should be replaced or repaired? 
i95520/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the incorporation of a notification period in the legislation, within which consumers would have to notify the producer of the fault? 
i957221/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the labeling of chocolate products that contain vegetable fats other than cocoa? 
i957223/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the listing of the origin of honey on the label? 
i957223/3 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the labeling of honey intended for industrial use? 
i97628/1 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the protection of consumers and right holders’ rights with respect to the transfer of protected work over the Internet? 
i97628/3 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the application of the “fair compensation” principle to the approximately fifteen exceptions to the directive (for educational purposes, for use by handicapped persons, etc.)? 
i99329/1 Should propellant gases (butane, iso-butane, and propane) be allowed to be used for water-based emulsion sprays? 
i99456/1 What are the preferences of the member states concerning the extension of the derogation of the directive that regulates a certain testing regime for bovine animals and swine? 
i99487/1 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the timing of the introduction of the first step (with less detail) of the compulsory labeling system for beef and beef products? 
i99487/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the timing of the introduction of the second step (with more detail) of the compulsory labelling system for beef and beef products? 
i99487/3 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the level of detail on the label during the first stage of the compulsory labeling system for beef and beef products? 
i99487/4 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the level of detail on the label during the second stage of the compulsory labeling system for beef and beef products? 
i9955/1 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the extensiveness of the labeling of fishery products? 
i99594/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the strength of the health warning of tobacco products? 
i99594/3 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the disclosure of more product information on tobacco products? 
i99594/5 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the ban of product descriptions such as “light” and “medium” for tobacco products? 
i00855/3 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the use of talc in the processing of olive oil? 
i98135/1 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the prohibition of the use of hen cages from the first of January 2012? 
i98135/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the timing for the improvement of the general conditions of the hen cages? 
i98135/3 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the minimum of cm sq of cage area for each hen? 
i98135/4 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the timing for the introduction of a compulsory system of cm sq of cage area for hens? 
i98135/5 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the timing for prohibiting hen cages after the first of January 2009? 
i98450/1 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the definition of a rare illness (requiring orphan medicines)? 
i99608/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the extent to which low fat content milk should be included in the subsidy system and thus be promoted? 
List of Institutional Issues Analyzed in Table Two  
i00303/1 Should the termination of the temporal protection of refugees be decided by qualified majority voting or by unanimity? 
i957223/1 How much discretion should the implementation committee (comitology committee) of the honey directive have? 
i99260/1 How much discretion should the implementation committee (comitology committee) of the asylum directive have and where should it be located? 
i99348/2 Should the European Commission have external competence in the area of patents? 
i99382/2 How extensively should national delegates be represented in the Advisory Committee on Fisheries? 
i99440/1 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the institutional place of the employment committee: in particular, whether it should be within the sphere of the Commission and Council? 
i99594/4 How extensive should the power of the Commission be in updating the tobacco directive? 
Document No. and DEU Data Set Issue No.Issues
List of Financial Issues Analyzed in Table Two  
i98329/1 How large should the amount of money allocated to the seven-year Socrates (education) program be? 
i98768/1 How large should the civil protection program budget be every year? 
i99111/1 How high should the percentage of the budget of the European audiovisual observatory be that must be paid with EU funds? 
i99364/1 Which mechanism will be initiated if the year’s agricultural budget is overspent? 
i99382/1 How extensively should a fishery advisory council be financed by the EU and by the member states? 
i99494/2 How large should the budget be that is assigned by the European Commission for financial and technical assistance to Mediterranean countries between 2000 and 2006? 
i996581/1 How large should the amount of money for training measures for people working in the European audiovisual industry 2001–2005 be? 
i996582/1 How much money should be allocated to the development, distribution, and promotion of these audiovisual trainings? 
i996582/5 How much money should be allocated to the pilot studies in the area of vocational training in the European audiovisual industry? 
List of Consumer Issues Analyzed in Table Two  
i00855/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the use and labeling of mixtures of olive oil and vegetable oil? 
i00855/5 What are the preferences of the member states on the labeling of olive oil regarding the country of processing? 
i95520/1 What are the preferences of the member states on the party (consumer or producer) that should take the decision on whether a defective product should be replaced or repaired? 
i95520/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the incorporation of a notification period in the legislation, within which consumers would have to notify the producer of the fault? 
i957221/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the labeling of chocolate products that contain vegetable fats other than cocoa? 
i957223/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the listing of the origin of honey on the label? 
i957223/3 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the labeling of honey intended for industrial use? 
i97628/1 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the protection of consumers and right holders’ rights with respect to the transfer of protected work over the Internet? 
i97628/3 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the application of the “fair compensation” principle to the approximately fifteen exceptions to the directive (for educational purposes, for use by handicapped persons, etc.)? 
i99329/1 Should propellant gases (butane, iso-butane, and propane) be allowed to be used for water-based emulsion sprays? 
i99456/1 What are the preferences of the member states concerning the extension of the derogation of the directive that regulates a certain testing regime for bovine animals and swine? 
i99487/1 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the timing of the introduction of the first step (with less detail) of the compulsory labeling system for beef and beef products? 
i99487/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the timing of the introduction of the second step (with more detail) of the compulsory labelling system for beef and beef products? 
i99487/3 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the level of detail on the label during the first stage of the compulsory labeling system for beef and beef products? 
i99487/4 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the level of detail on the label during the second stage of the compulsory labeling system for beef and beef products? 
i9955/1 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the extensiveness of the labeling of fishery products? 
i99594/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the strength of the health warning of tobacco products? 
i99594/3 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the disclosure of more product information on tobacco products? 
i99594/5 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the ban of product descriptions such as “light” and “medium” for tobacco products? 
i00855/3 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the use of talc in the processing of olive oil? 
i98135/1 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the prohibition of the use of hen cages from the first of January 2012? 
i98135/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the timing for the improvement of the general conditions of the hen cages? 
i98135/3 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the minimum of cm sq of cage area for each hen? 
i98135/4 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the timing for the introduction of a compulsory system of cm sq of cage area for hens? 
i98135/5 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the timing for prohibiting hen cages after the first of January 2009? 
i98450/1 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the definition of a rare illness (requiring orphan medicines)? 
i99608/2 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the extent to which low fat content milk should be included in the subsidy system and thus be promoted? 
List of Institutional Issues Analyzed in Table Two  
i00303/1 Should the termination of the temporal protection of refugees be decided by qualified majority voting or by unanimity? 
i957223/1 How much discretion should the implementation committee (comitology committee) of the honey directive have? 
i99260/1 How much discretion should the implementation committee (comitology committee) of the asylum directive have and where should it be located? 
i99348/2 Should the European Commission have external competence in the area of patents? 
i99382/2 How extensively should national delegates be represented in the Advisory Committee on Fisheries? 
i99440/1 What are the preferences of the member states regarding the institutional place of the employment committee: in particular, whether it should be within the sphere of the Commission and Council? 
i99594/4 How extensive should the power of the Commission be in updating the tobacco directive? 
This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International (CC BY 4.0) license, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. For a full description of the license, please visit https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/legalcode.