Abstract
We exploit the variation in admission cutoffs across colleges at a leading Indian university to estimate the causal effects of enrolling in a selective college on cognitive attainment, economic preferences, and Big Five personality traits. Using a regression discontinuity design, we find that enrolling in a selective college improves university exam scores of the marginally admitted women and makes them less overconfident and less risk averse, while men in selective colleges experience a decline in extraversion and conscientiousness. We find differences in peer quality and rank concerns to be driving our findings.
I. Introduction
COGNITIVE ability, completed years of schooling, and test scores have long been considered important determinants of success in life (Hanushek & Woessmann, 2008; Oreopoulos & Salvanes, 2011). However, there is now increasing evidence that suggests economic preferences and socioemotional traits like self-control, risk appetite, and competitiveness to be as important in determining educational attainment, labor market outcomes, and overall well-being (Almlund et al., 2011; Buser, Niederle, & Oosterbeek, 2014; Jaeger et al., 2010).
College is an important milestone that is believed to develop both cognitive and socioemotional aspects of an individual's human capital. Consequently, there is great emphasis on enrolling in selective colleges that are expected to provide high-achieving peers, better teachers, and stronger alumni networks and serve as a signal for higher ability. Experiencing such an environment for three or four years is likely to shape one's broader skill set. The literature on school and college quality reports both positive and nonsignificant effects of exposure to more selective educational institutions on academic outcomes (Abdulkadiroğlu, Angrist, & Pathak, 2014; Ajayi, 2014; Jackson, 2010; Lucas & Mbiti, 2014; Pop-Eleches & Urquiola, 2013; Saavedra 2009; Sekhri, 2020). Interestingly, it remains mostly silent on the accompanying behavioral responses and underlying mechanisms that may explain these mixed results. For instance, being in a more selective educational institution can also present a challenge for students who have a low ordinal rank relative to their peers. Students' perceptions of self-abilities based on relative rank could lead to behavioral responses that may dilute or negate the overall gains from attending a more selective educational institution (Elsner & Isphording, 2017; Murphy & Weinhardt, 2020; Pop-Eleches & Urquiola, 2013).
The objective of this paper is to examine the returns from exposure to a selective college on academic outcomes, as well as on measures of risk taking, competitiveness, overconfidence, and Big Five personality traits.1 To the best of our knowledge, this is the first paper to causally identify the effects of enrolling in a more selective college on socioemotional and behavioral aspects of human capital accumulation. In doing so, we use rich student-level data in a regression discontinuity design to address the selection problem arising from sorting, that is, high-achieving students self-select into more selective colleges while low-achieving students sort into less selective colleges.
We analyze data from the University of Delhi (DU), one of the top public universities in India, to estimate the returns to college quality across a range of colleges with varying levels of selectivity that are all within the same educational context. Admission into colleges within the DU system is based on the incoming cohorts' average scores on the high school exit exam. This gives rise to college-discipline-specific admission cutoffs that determine an individual's eligibility to enroll in a specific discipline in a college. We exploit students' inability to manipulate this admission cutoff and compare outcomes of students just above the cutoff to those just below the cutoff to estimate the causal impact of enrolling in a more selective college.
Value-added models of learning will predict better academic and nonacademic outcomes for students just above the cutoff enrolled in more selective colleges. The company of more able peers can allow richer learning opportunities, provide a more dynamic environment for group interactions, and serve as a motivation to work harder to keep up with the competition (Jain & Kapoor, 2015; Feld & Zölitz, 2017). However, the marginal students, those just above the cutoff, are also the worst off relative to their peer group (“small fish in a big pond”), while those just below the cutoff are relatively better than their peers (“big fish in a small pond”). The marginally admitted student has a lower relative rank among her peer group that could lower her academic self-concept resulting in a detrimental or zero impact on not just her future academic performance but also her behavior and personality (Marsh et al., 2008).2 Therefore, students above the cutoff face trade-offs between the positive effects of higher-ability peer environments and negative effects of low relative rank (Cicala, Fryer, & Spenkuch, 2018; Elsner & Isphording, 2017, 2018; Fabregas, 2017; Murphy & Weinhardt, 2020). Consequently, the net effects of enrolling in a more selective college could go in either direction.3
We combine data from a series of incentivized tasks and socioeconomic surveys administered to over 2,000 undergraduate students at different colleges of DU to examine the returns to enrollment in more selective college environments. The first outcome of interest is academic attainment as measured by scores on standardized university-level exams. Next, we examine impacts on economic preferences such as competitiveness, overconfidence, and risk elicited using incentivized tasks. The final set of outcomes deals with the Big Five traits (Openness to Experience, Conscientiousness, Extraversion, Agreeableness, and Emotional Stability), a broadly accepted taxonomy of personality traits.4
Several interesting findings emerge from our analysis. First, enrollment in a selective college leads to gains in scores on standardized university-level exams for marginally admitted women, and their higher attendance rates are possibly driving this effect. Second, exposure to more able peer environments in these selective colleges makes women less risk averse and less overconfident. Third, we find that marginally admitted men experience a significant decline in extraversion and conscientiousness as compared to their counterparts in less selective colleges, representing small fish in a big pond effects. Fourth, we find suggestive evidence that the returns to enrolling in selective colleges vary by college quality, with men's personality traits being more susceptible to concerns over low relative ranks at the top end of the college quality distribution. Finally, we do not find significant variation in measures of teacher quality across colleges implying differences in peer quality and rank concerns to be driving our results.
Our findings are consistent with recent work on related topics. For instance, Murphy and Weinhardt (2020) exploit idiosyncratic variation in cohort composition among primary school children in the United Kingdom to find that students with the same ability but higher relative rank perform significantly better in secondary school. Applying a similar identification strategy to U.S. data, Elsner and Isphording (2017) find that students with higher ordinal rank are more likely to complete high school and enter and graduate from college. Elsner and Isphording (2018) also find that low relative rank increases the likelihood of engaging in risky and violent behavior, and they attribute this to diminished future expectations and perceived status arising from lower ordinal rank. Fabregas (2017), using data from Mexico City middle schools, also finds that students who are just above the cutoff express lower perseverance and aspirations to attend college. Interestingly, the effects we observe for behavior and personality traits are larger than those for standardized university exam scores. This is in line with findings in Sacerdote (2011): the peer effects in higher education are greater on social outcomes related to memberships in sorority/fraternity, smoking, and drinking than on academic achievement. Overall, our findings contribute to understanding the gender-differentiated cognitive and noncognitive returns to postsecondary education.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The institutional setting and college admissions process at the University of Delhi, sampling strategy, and data are described in section II. The empirical strategy is outlined in section III. All results and robustness checks are presented in section IV. Concluding remarks follow in section V.
II. Background and Data
University of Delhi (DU) is one of India's top public universities and offers three-year undergraduate education to approximately 160,000 full-time students. DU consists of 79 colleges, each offering degrees in multiple disciplines such as science, commerce, arts, and humanities. Each college is an independent entity with its own campus, faculty, students, and teaching conducted within the colleges. However, the curriculum and all exams for each discipline are determined centrally by DU and are identical across all colleges. Teacher salaries are also the same across colleges in DU. These are unique features of DU; in most other settings, these factors vary across educational institutions.
A. College Admissions Process
College admissions for most disciplines in DU are based on the student's high school exit exam score computed as the average of best of four out of five subjects, including language.5 In the first two weeks of June each year, students apply using the Common Pre-Admission Form where they state their high school exit exam scores and select the colleges and the disciplines within the colleges they wish to apply to. The application costs INR 100 (approximately 1.5 USD). This form can be purchased and submitted at multiple centers across Delhi, thereby minimizing any time costs arising from traveling to several colleges.
After the applications period is complete, based on capacity constraints and the incoming cohort's average score, each discipline within a college announces the cutoff scores that determine admission into the specific college and discipline.6 All applicants above the cutoff in the discipline are eligible for admission in the college discipline. Since there is excess demand for high-quality colleges, the cutoffs for these colleges are significantly and systematically higher than the low-quality colleges. If there are vacancies, colleges announce a second list with lower cutoffs. This process continues for several rounds as colleges gradually lower their cutoffs until all spots are filled.7 As expected, the more selective colleges fill their seats within the first couple of rounds, while the less selective ones sequentially lower their cutoffs, taking at times up to ten rounds to fill their seats. As a result, the DU college admission process creates an environment where students who enroll in more selective colleges are exposed to high-achieving peers as compared to students enrolled in less selective colleges.
B. Sampling Strategy
Our study was conducted from January to March 2014. We constructed our sample in the following manner. First, to ensure representativeness along the distribution of college quality, we obtained the list of all 79 colleges affiliated with DU. Second, we drew a list of 58 colleges that offer disciplines in commerce and/or economics.8 These 58 colleges can be further categorized into daytime coeducational colleges (32), daytime women-only colleges (17), and evening coeducational colleges (9). Of the 32 daytime coeducational colleges, we further exclude 7 colleges that offer too few disciplines or use any criteria other than high school exit exam scores for admissions, resulting in a list of 25 target colleges. After considering admission cutoffs for each of these 25 colleges for three years (2011–2013) and budget constraints, we identified 18 colleges that had consistently ranked cutoffs across the three years for economics and commerce, of which we could implement our study in 15 colleges with varying cutoffs.
We focus on the two disciplines of economics and commerce for a number of reasons, in addition to cost considerations. First, enrollment in economics and commerce is usually higher than in most other disciplines. For example, in DU in 2011, the total enrollment in the first year for economics and commerce was over 10,200 students, accounting for 28% of total student intake for honors disciplines.9 Second, economics and commerce have higher cutoffs across all colleges as compared to other popular disciplines such as history, political science, mathematics, and English. To illustrate, in our sample of fifteen colleges, in 2011, the average cutoff for commerce and economics is 91%. The average cutoffs for other disciplines are history (74%), political science (75.8%), mathematics (82.8%), and English (77.13%). Third, and importantly, admission into economics and commerce is based solely on high school exit exam scores, facilitating the regression discontinuity design, while for some other disciplines, the admission process entails a combination of written entrance exams, high school exit exam scores, and interviews.
We also examine whether colleges in our sample are representative of the remaining colleges in DU in terms of their selectivity. Figure A1 in the online appendix shows that the distribution of cutoffs in economics and commerce in our sample of 15 colleges overlaps with those of the remaining 43 of the 58 colleges, and the Kolmogorov-Smirnov tests do not reject the null of equal distributions (-value 0.922 and 0.941 for economics and commerce, respectively), suggesting that our sample of colleges is representative of the remaining colleges in DU.
Further, a wealth of evidence suggests that colleges in DU are among the most favored choices for economics and commerce. India Today, a well-known Indian magazine, publishes an annual ranking of the top fifty colleges across the country for various disciplines. This list is based on a perceptions-based survey and factual survey. In 2011 and 2012 (the years of admission for the sample of students in our survey), for the categories of commerce and arts (economics falls within arts category), several colleges of DU feature in the top fifty colleges across India.10 Similarly, the National Institutional Ranking Framework (NIRF), a recent initiative by the Indian Ministry of Human Resource Development, ranks higher education institutions across the country on a range of parameters. According to the latest data for 2019 for undergraduate programs in arts and commerce, eleven of top twenty colleges are in DU.11
In the region of Delhi and neighboring states, DU is the leading university offering these nontechnical disciplines. Other public universities in the area offering similar disciplines are quite few, much smaller, and are not considered as reputable (Borker, 2017). Private universities are substantially more expensive than DU and not as competitive. In the NIRF, none of the other high-ranking colleges in Delhi are non-DU and no other high-ranking colleges are in close proximity of Delhi. It is also expensive to relocate to a different city, especially as most colleges have limited on-campus housing facilities.12 Further, nationally representative data such as the Indian Census and National Sample Surveys show that migration among youth is low for education and accounts for only a small share of the migrant stream. Most migrants move within state (Chandrasekhar & Sharma, 2014). This suggests that among those who narrowly fail to get admitted into more selective DU colleges, a less selective college in DU is likely to be preferable to attending other universities in Delhi and surrounding states.13
C. Data
We collected data on approximately 2,000 second- and third-year students enrolled in economics and commerce disciplines in these fifteen colleges. To conduct the surveys during class hours, we obtained approval from the college principals, and collaborated with teachers at these colleges to determine the specific session timings. Upon arriving in the classrooms, teachers introduced the research team, and students were told that we would be conducting a decision-making study and survey, that participation was voluntary, and that they would be monetarily compensated for their time.
In the first part of the study, we conducted incentivized experiments to elicit economic preferences. First, to capture subjects' competitiveness and overconfidence, we used a simple number-addition task (similar to Bartling et al., 2009). After a practice session, participants had to predict their performance in advance and also choose between a piece-rate and tournament compensation scheme. Under the piece-rate scheme, INR 10 was paid for every correct answer. Under the tournament scheme, INR 20 was paid for every correct answer if the subject outperformed a randomly selected student of DU who had solved the questions earlier.14 We define competitiveness as a dummy that takes a value 1 if the subject chose the tournament compensation scheme and 0 if the subject chose the piece-rate compensation scheme. As in Dasgupta et al. (2017), we define overconfidence as the ratio of the predicted performance to the student's performance in the actual task.15
Second, to measure risk preferences, we used the Gneezy and Potters (1997) investment task. In this, subjects allocated a portion of their endowment (INR 150) to a risky lottery and set aside the remainder. If they won the lottery based on a die roll, the invested amount was tripled, and they also got any amount they set aside. Conversely, if they lost the lottery, they received only the amount that was set aside. We define risk preference as the proportion allocated to the risky lottery in the investment game.
In the second part of the study, we implemented a socioeconomic survey that collected details on family background characteristics, school and college information, academic performance, and participation in extracurricular activities. To measure cognitive attainment, we collected data on standardized university exam scores.16 To measure personality traits, we administered the ten-item Big Five inventory (Gosling, Rentfrow, & Swann, 2003) that consists of the following traits. Openness to Experience captures a tendency to be open to new aesthetic, cultural, or intellectual experiences. Conscientiousness refers to a tendency to be organized, responsible, and hard working. Extraversion relates to an outward orientation of one's interests and energies oriented toward the outer world of people, characterized by sociability. Agreeableness is related to the tendency to act in a cooperative and unselfish manner. Emotional Stability (opposite of Neuroticism) is predictability and consistency in emotional reactions with absence of rapid mood changes.
Overall, we conducted sixty sessions with approximately 35 subjects per session. Each session lasted about 75 minutes. No feedback was provided between or after the tasks. All subjects received a show-up fee of INR 150. The average additional payment was INR 230. All subjects participated only once in the study. To minimize wealth effects, additional payments were based on one of the randomly chosen incentivized tasks. Instructions for the incentivized tasks are available in online appendix B.
III. Empirical Specification and Sample Description
A. Empirical Specification
For estimating the returns to college quality, we first group colleges based on their relative selectivity. We use admission cutoffs, as exogenously announced by the individual colleges, as the criteria to sort the fifteen colleges in our sample into four ordered categories ranging from 1 (highest rank) to 4 (lowest rank). As a result, colleges with similar cutoffs appear under the same group/rank. In table A3 in the online appendix, for each of the four ranks, we present the means and standard deviations of cutoffs within each rank. As expected, the average cutoffs are greater in the higher-ranked colleges. Further, the cutoffs appear to show greater dispersion as one moves down the ranks. This is not surprising as less selective colleges are likely to have more heterogeneity than more selective colleges. A similar pattern emerges if we examine the means and standard deviations of high school exit exam scores within a rank. Overall, table A3 shows that students who perform similarly in high school exit exams are grouped within each rank.
Next, for each rank, we compute the minimum score required for admission into the group. These cutoffs vary by student type where students differ in their current discipline (commerce and economics), academic track in high school (science, commerce, and humanities), year of entry (2011 and 2012), and gender (men and women). For example, a student seeking admission into economics, having studied science in high school faces a different cutoff from a student who studied commerce in high school. Thus, for each rank of colleges, we get a set of cutoffs that define the minimum score required by each student type for admission into that college rank.
We then combine the cutoffs, ranks, and student data. For our analysis, from an initial sample of approximately 2,000 students, we exclude all students whose admissions were not based on their high school exit exam scores. This includes students belonging to historically disadvantaged backgrounds (Scheduled Castes, Scheduled Tribes, and Other Backward Classes) for whom affirmative action policies mandate a fixed number of seats (29.3%); students admitted on the basis of excellence in sports or other extracurricular activities (4.8%); those who transferred across colleges after enrollment or switched disciplines within a college (0.3%); and those providing insufficient information (1.3%). These exclusions leave us with 1,331 students.
Since we are interested in estimating the returns to enrollment in a more selective college group, we now construct three samples using our sample of 1,331 students. In the first constructed sample, colleges in rank 1 are assigned to the treated group/more selective colleges, and the remaining colleges (in ranks 2, 3, and 4) are assigned as comparison group/less selective colleges. In the next sample, colleges in ranks 1 and 2 are assigned to the treated group, and the remaining colleges (in ranks 3 and 4) are assigned to the comparison group. Finally, a third sample is constructed where colleges ranked 1, 2, and 3 are assigned to the treated group and colleges in rank 4 are in the comparison group. Following Abdulkadiroğlu et al. (2014), Jackson (2010), and Pop-Eleches and Urquiola (2013), we construct our final analysis sample by stacking the three samples together and estimate a single average treatment effect measuring the impact of enrollment in a relatively selective college. The stacking method has two advantages. First, it allows us to estimate the effect of enrolling in a more selective college over the distribution of college quality. Second, this methodology increases the sample size and, consequently, power. Note that stacking our sample can plausibly make a student appear at most three times in the data. However, as we only use observations near the cutoff for our analysis (i.e., within a 5 percentage point window), it results in 868 students appearing more than once in the final analysis sample of 2,393 observations.
The coefficient estimate on TR in equation (2) gives us the local average treatment effect (LATE) of being enrolled in a more selective college. As the literature on the effects of school and college quality documents significant heterogeneity by gender (e.g., Hastings, Kane, & Staiger, 2006; Jackson, 2010; Kling, Ludwig, & Katz, 2005), we also report our results for men and women separately.
Since the running variable is discrete, following Lee and Card (2008), we cluster our standard errors with respect to 0.25 bins of the running variable.18 The choice of the bandwidth is an important issue in RD analysis. Since we have various outcome variables, we fix the bandwidth to be 5 percentage points for the main analysis. In section IVC, we show that our results are robust to using outcome-specific optimal bandwidths.
As we wish to estimate the effects of enrolling in a more selective college, the ideal sample would comprise students/DU applicants who strictly prefer more selective colleges to the less selective ones such that a score above (below) the relevant cutoff would lead to admission in a more (less) selective college. As explained in section IIA, DU follows a decentralized admission process wherein applicants fill in a common form to indicate the college disciplines they wish to apply to.19 This process does not gather the preferences of the applicants over colleges and/or disciplines, and all we observe is the current discipline that the student is enrolled in, her high school exit exam score, and the cutoffs at the time of admission. Nonetheless, with a fixed supply of seats, the higher cutoffs at colleges are a reflection of excess demand for those seats. It is then reasonable to assume that the average student prefers admission into a college with higher cutoffs than one with lower cutoffs. We discuss this further in section IVC.
B. Summary Statistics
In table 1, we present descriptive statistics for our sample. In panel A, we see that average score on standardized university-level exams, our measure of academic attainment during college, is 70% with no significant gender differences. In panel B, we summarize choices in the incentivized tasks: competitiveness, overconfidence, and risk. Thirty-one percent of the subjects are considered competitive as they choose the tournament payment scheme. The average student is overconfident as the ratio of the expected number of correct answers to the number correctly solved in the actual task is 1.6, significantly higher than 1. These findings are also supported by other papers that find that about one-third of subjects choose the tournament wage scheme and often irrationally overestimate their own abilities (Dasgupta et al., 2015; Niederle & Vesterlund, 2007). Finally, the average investment of 46.6% in the risky asset is in the range of 44.67% to 70.86% observed for student populations (Charness & Viceisza, 2016). The significant gender differences in competitiveness and risk aversion are in accordance with previous work (see Niederle, 2016, for a review).
Summary Statistics
. | Full Sample . | Men . | Women . | Difference . |
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
A: Cognitive attainment | ||||
University exam score | 70.44 | 70.19 | 70.64 | −0.45 |
(7.39) | (7.43) | (7.36) | ||
B: Economic preferences | ||||
Competitiveness | 0.31 | 0.41 | 0.24 | 0.17*** |
(0.46) | (0.49) | (0.43) | ||
Overconfidence | 1.64 | 1.66 | 1.63 | 0.03 |
(1.22) | (1.20) | (1.24) | ||
Risk preference | 46.59 | 49.88 | 43.99 | 5.89*** |
(19.08) | (21.71) | (16.24) | ||
C: Personality traits | ||||
Extraversion score | 4.77 | 4.69 | 4.83 | −0.14** |
(1.43) | (1.43) | (1.42) | ||
Agreeableness score | 5.20 | 4.97 | 5.38 | −0.41*** |
(1.16) | (1.16) | (1.12) | ||
Conscientiousness score | 5.31 | 5.20 | 5.40 | −0.20*** |
(1.26) | (1.29) | (1.23) | ||
Emotional stability score | 4.54 | 4.65 | 4.45 | 0.20*** |
(1.38) | (1.40) | (1.36) | ||
Openness to experience score | 5.42 | 5.44 | 5.41 | 0.03 |
(1.12) | (1.10) | (1.14) | ||
D: Background characteristics | ||||
Age | 19.66 | 19.69 | 19.65 | 0.04 |
(0.86) | (0.86) | (0.86) | ||
Religion | 0.92 | 0.92 | 0.93 | −0.01 |
(0.27) | (0.28) | (0.26) | ||
Private School | 0.85 | 0.85 | 0.84 | 0.01 |
(0.36) | (0.36) | (0.36) | ||
Income | 0.30 | 0.30 | 0.31 | −0.01 |
(0.46) | (0.46) | (0.46) | ||
Mother's Education | 0.75 | 0.73 | 0.77 | −0.04** |
(0.43) | (0.44) | (0.42) | ||
Father's Education | 0.78 | 0.78 | 0.79 | −0.00 |
(0.41) | (0.41) | (0.41) |
. | Full Sample . | Men . | Women . | Difference . |
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
A: Cognitive attainment | ||||
University exam score | 70.44 | 70.19 | 70.64 | −0.45 |
(7.39) | (7.43) | (7.36) | ||
B: Economic preferences | ||||
Competitiveness | 0.31 | 0.41 | 0.24 | 0.17*** |
(0.46) | (0.49) | (0.43) | ||
Overconfidence | 1.64 | 1.66 | 1.63 | 0.03 |
(1.22) | (1.20) | (1.24) | ||
Risk preference | 46.59 | 49.88 | 43.99 | 5.89*** |
(19.08) | (21.71) | (16.24) | ||
C: Personality traits | ||||
Extraversion score | 4.77 | 4.69 | 4.83 | −0.14** |
(1.43) | (1.43) | (1.42) | ||
Agreeableness score | 5.20 | 4.97 | 5.38 | −0.41*** |
(1.16) | (1.16) | (1.12) | ||
Conscientiousness score | 5.31 | 5.20 | 5.40 | −0.20*** |
(1.26) | (1.29) | (1.23) | ||
Emotional stability score | 4.54 | 4.65 | 4.45 | 0.20*** |
(1.38) | (1.40) | (1.36) | ||
Openness to experience score | 5.42 | 5.44 | 5.41 | 0.03 |
(1.12) | (1.10) | (1.14) | ||
D: Background characteristics | ||||
Age | 19.66 | 19.69 | 19.65 | 0.04 |
(0.86) | (0.86) | (0.86) | ||
Religion | 0.92 | 0.92 | 0.93 | −0.01 |
(0.27) | (0.28) | (0.26) | ||
Private School | 0.85 | 0.85 | 0.84 | 0.01 |
(0.36) | (0.36) | (0.36) | ||
Income | 0.30 | 0.30 | 0.31 | −0.01 |
(0.46) | (0.46) | (0.46) | ||
Mother's Education | 0.75 | 0.73 | 0.77 | −0.04** |
(0.43) | (0.44) | (0.42) | ||
Father's Education | 0.78 | 0.78 | 0.79 | −0.00 |
(0.41) | (0.41) | (0.41) |
Religion is an indicator variable for being a Hindu; income is an indicator variable for monthly family income being below Rs 50,000; mother's and father's education are indicator variables for tertiary education; private school is an indicator variable for graduation from a private high school. Personality traits' scores range from 0 to 7. For second- and third-year students, we have the average exam scores based on three semesters and five semesters respectively. Sample restricted to /5 window around the cutoff. Significant at 10%, 5%, and 1%.
In panel C, we summarize subjects' Big Five personality traits. Subjects report a higher score on agreeableness, conscientiousness, and openness to experience than they do for extraversion and emotional stability. Women are more extrovert, conscientious, and agreeable, and less emotionally stable than males. Schmitt et al. (2008) note similar gender differences in personality traits across several cultural contexts. Finally, in panel D, we present descriptive statistics on background characteristics. The average age of the students is close to 20. Over 90% are Hindus (the dominant religion in India), 85% attended a private high school, and 75% to 78% have either a highly educated mother or father (college degree or higher). A third of the sample comes from low-income households (those earning less than INR 50,000 per month or INR 600,000 per year).20
C. Testing the Validity of the RD Design
The RD model relies on two assumptions: (a) there is no precise manipulation of the assignment variable around the cutoff, and (b) the probability of being enrolled in a more selective college is discontinuous at the cutoff.
where is the vector of predetermined background characteristics and the right-hand side variables are as defined in equations (1) and (2). The results from these regressions are presented in the online appendix table A4. We find that the impact of the treatment indicator, that is, being eligible to enroll in a more selective college on the predetermined variables, is mostly small and never significantly different from 0, confirming the validity of the RD design. The corresponding graphical representations are provided in figures A2 to A4 in the online appendix. However, as we do not have student-level panel data, we are unable to rule out discontinuities in pretreatment outcome variables around the cutoff.
First-Stage Discontinuity
. | Full Sample . | Males . | Females . |
---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
Without controls | 0.680*** | 0.698*** | 0.626*** |
(0.066) | (0.086) | (0.078) | |
Observations | 2,393 | 1,059 | 1,334 |
With controls | 0.681*** | 0.702*** | 0.629*** |
(0.063) | (0.082) | (0.074) | |
Observations | 2,368 | 1,043 | 1,325 |
. | Full Sample . | Males . | Females . |
---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
Without controls | 0.680*** | 0.698*** | 0.626*** |
(0.066) | (0.086) | (0.078) | |
Observations | 2,393 | 1,059 | 1,334 |
With controls | 0.681*** | 0.702*** | 0.629*** |
(0.063) | (0.082) | (0.074) | |
Observations | 2,368 | 1,043 | 1,325 |
This table shows the first-stage discontinuity results using a flexible second-order polynomial described in the text. We control for mother's education, father's education, private school enrollment, age, income, and religion in all specifications (see notes in table 1 for variable definitions). All regressions also include cutoff and month of survey fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at 0.25 bins of the centered high school exit exam score level are reported in parentheses. Significant at 10%, 5%, and 1%.
IV. Results
A. Effects on Cognition, Economic Behavior, and Personality
This figure plots residual terms obtained by regressing average peer quality on cutoff fixed effects against distance from the threshold.
This figure plots residual terms obtained by regressing average peer quality on cutoff fixed effects against distance from the threshold.
Average Peer Quality
. | Full Sample . | Males . | Females . |
---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
Av. grade 12 score | 2.477*** | 2.461*** | 2.713*** |
(0.244) | (0.334) | (0.369) | |
Observations | 2,368 | 1,043 | 1,325 |
Av. grade 10 score | 2.932*** | 2.597*** | 3.371*** |
(0.291) | (0.440) | (0.422) | |
Observations | 2,361 | 1,041 | 1,320 |
. | Full Sample . | Males . | Females . |
---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
Av. grade 12 score | 2.477*** | 2.461*** | 2.713*** |
(0.244) | (0.334) | (0.369) | |
Observations | 2,368 | 1,043 | 1,325 |
Av. grade 10 score | 2.932*** | 2.597*** | 3.371*** |
(0.291) | (0.440) | (0.422) | |
Observations | 2,361 | 1,041 | 1,320 |
This table reports instrumental variable estimates using the flexible second-order polynomial described in the text. We control for mother's education, father's education, private school enrollment, age, income, and religion in all specifications (see notes in table 1 for variable definitions). All regressions also include cutoff and month of survey fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at 0.25 bins of the centered high school exit exam score level are reported in parentheses. Significant at 10%, 5%, and 1%.
Next, in table 4, we present the impacts of enrollment in a more selective college on cognitive attainment (in column 1), economic preferences (in columns 2–4), and personality traits (in columns 5–9) for the pooled sample, men, and women in panels A, B, and C, respectively. While curriculum and exams are the same within a discipline across colleges of DU, marginal admission into a more selective college exposes students to high-achieving peers and changes their relative position in the peer ability distribution. Looking at the effects on the standardized university-level exam scores for the pooled sample in column 1 of panel A, we find that compared to students in less selective colleges, marginally admitted students in more selective colleges experience a 1.127 percentage point increase in their average university exam scores. Upon further examining these effects by gender, it is apparent that this overall impact is driven by the significant effects on women's test scores with no statistically significant effect for men (column 1, panels B and C). In particular, women in more selective colleges on average score 2.8 percentage points higher on the university exams relative to women in less selective colleges, resulting in about 4% improvement over the comparison group's mean of 69%. Our finding that women make significant academic gains from exposure to more able peer environments with little or no accompanying effects on men has also been found in other studies (Angrist, Lang, & Oreopoulos, 2009; Hastings et al., 2006; Jackson, 2010). Further, we show later in section IVB that women (but not men) enrolled in more selective colleges are almost 32 percentage points more likely to have higher attendance rates than their counterparts in less selective colleges. This gender difference in attendance rates is likely to explain the observed gender gap in academic returns to more selective college and peer environments.
Returns to College Quality: Main Results
. | . | Economic Preferences . | Personality Traits . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | University . | . | . | Risk . | . | . | . | Emotional . | Openness to . |
. | Exam Score . | Competitiveness . | Overconfidence . | Preference . | Extraversion . | Agreeableness . | Conscientiousness . | Stability . | Experience . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . | (9) . |
A: Full Sample | |||||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | 1.127* | 0.116 | −0.288** | 0.153 | −0.285** | 0.037 | −0.262 | 0.166 | −0.034 |
(0.681) | (0.214) | (0.125) | (0.188) | (0.139) | (0.114) | (0.205) | (0.120) | (0.135) | |
[0.098] | [0.643] | [0.068] | [0.643] | [0.258] | [0.508] | [0.369] | [0.369] | [0.508] | |
Observations | 2,346 | 2,365 | 2,335 | 2,359 | 2,331 | 2,318 | 2,340 | 2,329 | 2,328 |
B: Males | |||||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | −0.654 | 0.191 | −0.135 | −0.256 | −0.487** | −0.016 | −0.562** | −0.012 | −0.045 |
(1.401) | (0.259) | (0.224) | (0.262) | (0.194) | (0.188) | (0.221) | (0.250) | (0.119) | |
[0.641] | [1] | [1] | [1] | [0.031] | [1] | [0.031] | [1] | [1] | |
Observations | 1,030 | 1,043 | 1,035 | 1,038 | 1,021 | 1,013 | 1,029 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
C: Females | |||||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | 2.790** | 0.083 | −0.533* | 0.662*** | −0.287 | 0.057 | 0.077 | 0.380 | −0.026 |
(1.279) | (0.226) | (0.295) | (0.193) | (0.252) | (0.242) | (0.258) | (0.263) | (0.358) | |
[0.029] | [0.311] | [0.077] | [0.004] | [1] | [1] | [1] | [1] | [1] | |
Observations | 1,316 | 1,322 | 1,300 | 1,321 | 1,310 | 1,305 | 1,311 | 1,311 | 1,310 |
[male] [female] | |||||||||
-value | 0.131 | 0.684 | 0.365 | 0.002 | 0.571 | 0.84 | 0.012 | 0.346 | 0.964 |
. | . | Economic Preferences . | Personality Traits . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | University . | . | . | Risk . | . | . | . | Emotional . | Openness to . |
. | Exam Score . | Competitiveness . | Overconfidence . | Preference . | Extraversion . | Agreeableness . | Conscientiousness . | Stability . | Experience . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . | (9) . |
A: Full Sample | |||||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | 1.127* | 0.116 | −0.288** | 0.153 | −0.285** | 0.037 | −0.262 | 0.166 | −0.034 |
(0.681) | (0.214) | (0.125) | (0.188) | (0.139) | (0.114) | (0.205) | (0.120) | (0.135) | |
[0.098] | [0.643] | [0.068] | [0.643] | [0.258] | [0.508] | [0.369] | [0.369] | [0.508] | |
Observations | 2,346 | 2,365 | 2,335 | 2,359 | 2,331 | 2,318 | 2,340 | 2,329 | 2,328 |
B: Males | |||||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | −0.654 | 0.191 | −0.135 | −0.256 | −0.487** | −0.016 | −0.562** | −0.012 | −0.045 |
(1.401) | (0.259) | (0.224) | (0.262) | (0.194) | (0.188) | (0.221) | (0.250) | (0.119) | |
[0.641] | [1] | [1] | [1] | [0.031] | [1] | [0.031] | [1] | [1] | |
Observations | 1,030 | 1,043 | 1,035 | 1,038 | 1,021 | 1,013 | 1,029 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
C: Females | |||||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | 2.790** | 0.083 | −0.533* | 0.662*** | −0.287 | 0.057 | 0.077 | 0.380 | −0.026 |
(1.279) | (0.226) | (0.295) | (0.193) | (0.252) | (0.242) | (0.258) | (0.263) | (0.358) | |
[0.029] | [0.311] | [0.077] | [0.004] | [1] | [1] | [1] | [1] | [1] | |
Observations | 1,316 | 1,322 | 1,300 | 1,321 | 1,310 | 1,305 | 1,311 | 1,311 | 1,310 |
[male] [female] | |||||||||
-value | 0.131 | 0.684 | 0.365 | 0.002 | 0.571 | 0.84 | 0.012 | 0.346 | 0.964 |
This table reports instrumental variable estimates using the flexible second-order polynomial described in the text. We control for mother's education, father's education, private school enrollment, age, income, and religion in all specifications (see notes in table 1 for variable definitions). All regressions also include cutoff and month of survey fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at 0.25 bins of the centered high school exit exam score level are reported in parentheses. Significant at 10%, 5%, and 1%. Sharpened -values are reported in brackets.
We also estimate the returns to enrollment in a selective college on the three measures of economic preferences: competitiveness, overconfidence, and risk preference. The results are reported in columns 2 to 4 of table 4. Pooled results indicate that the marginally admitted student experiences a decline in overconfidence with no significant effects on competitiveness and risk preferences. On disaggregating the sample by gender, we observe overconfidence among marginally admitted women reduces by 0.53 SD. Our results for overconfidence show that marginal women in the more selective colleges experience a decline in overconfidence, and conversely, women below the cutoff, who are relatively high-achieving compared to their peers, become more overconfident. We hypothesize that the marginal female students in more selective colleges who are the small fish in a big pond may update their beliefs about their ability as they are surrounded by peers who are academically higher achieving than them.22
We also find that women enrolled in more selective colleges invest 0.66 SD more in the investment game, thereby being less risk averse than their female counterparts in the less selective colleges. To the extent that women are more risk averse than men, and this gender gap in risk preferences has implications for occupational choice and other economic decision making, this result suggests that enrollment in more selective colleges may result in a narrowing of this gender gap. Specifically, as per the expected utility theory framework and given the nature of the investment task (Gneezy & Potters, 1997) used to elicit risk preferences, in this task, only a risk-neutral person, or a person behaving under the expected value maximization (EV) criteria should choose to invest his or her entire endowment into the risky lottery. However, a risk-averse decision maker depending on his or her risk parameter would invest less than the full amount in the lottery. Consequently, a decrease in risk-averse behavior, that is, allocating a greater proportion of the endowment to the risky asset, can be interpreted as subjects getting closer to risk-neutral behavior, and/or choosing according to the EV criteria in the task. Since overconfidence is positively and risk aversion is negatively related to competitiveness, a decline in risk aversion and overconfidence could plausibly explain why we do not observe any significant effects on competitiveness. Further, we find no significant effects on male behavior.
The last set of estimates pertains to personality: Big Five traits of openness to experience, conscientiousness, extraversion, agreeableness, and emotional stability (see columns 5–9, table 4). In the pooled sample, we find that enrollment in a more selective college negatively affects extraversion by 0.28 SD with no effect on other traits. Extraversion and conscientiousness among marginally admitted men reduces by 0.48 SD and 0.56 SD, respectively. Taken together, these estimates for male students suggest a diminished self-concept stemming from their lower academic position within their college rank, resulting in negative effects on economically valuable personality traits, capturing small fish in a big pond effects. Murphy and Weinhardt (2020) also find men to be influenced more significantly on account of rank concerns. We find similar results using alternative measures. In results reported in table A5 in the online appendix, membership in college-level societies, another measure of extrovert behavior, is also lower among men enrolled in more selective colleges. Similarly, we also find that men at the margin of admission in more selective colleges report lower grit, which is highly correlated with conscientiousness. We also observe a decline in openness to experience and agreeableness for men, though neither is statistically significant. In light of findings that show that conscientiousness and extraversion matter for academic performance (Lundberg, 2013), the adverse effects on these personality traits for the marginally admitted men might explain why we observe no gains in exam scores for them.23 Finally, it is also possible that exposure to being in a selective college may affect some socioemotional skills with a lag and become prominent only in the long run, such that our effects are underestimated.
It is possible that impacts on measured outcomes differ by length of exposure. To examine this, we allow for the effects of college quality to vary by student cohorts (second and third year) and find that the main results in table 4 do not vary by cohort. These results are reported in table A6 in the online appendix.
B. Pathways
Owing to the design of the admissions process in colleges at DU, we have so far shown and argued that differences in peer quality and relative rank in the peer distribution are driving our main results. In this section, we explore a variety of other potential channels that could explain our main findings.
In column 1 in table 5, we examine differences in attendance rates.24 We construct a binary variable for high attendance that takes a value 1 if subjects report having class attendance rates of 75% and higher and 0 if attendance is below 75%. We find that while there is no significant difference for men in the probability of high attendance, women enrolled in selective colleges have a greater probability of high attendance than women in less selective colleges. This indicates that they are present in class more often and therefore have an opportunity to learn from and engage with their peers, making it one of the competing explanations for gains on cognitive and behavioral outcomes. This finding fits in with the general observed pattern of women having better study habits than men (Angrist et al., 2009; Hastings et al., 2006).
Pathways
. | Student Response . | Teachers . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | High Attendance . | Relatively Less Attendance . | External Tutorial . | Class Cancelled . | Student-Teacher Ratios . | ||
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | ||
A: Males | |||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | −0.128 | 0.322*** | 0.032 | 0.136 | 0.205 | ||
(0.086) | (0.090) | (0.095) | (0.123) | (0.538) | |||
Observations | 1,043 | 1,043 | 1,043 | 1,043 | 1,043 | ||
B: Females | |||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | 0.315** | −0.110 | −0.018 | 0.019 | −0.539 | ||
(0.126) | (0.136) | (0.108) | (0.150) | (0.967) | |||
Observations | 1,325 | 1,325 | 1,325 | 1,325 | 1,325 |
. | Student Response . | Teachers . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | High Attendance . | Relatively Less Attendance . | External Tutorial . | Class Cancelled . | Student-Teacher Ratios . | ||
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | ||
A: Males | |||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | −0.128 | 0.322*** | 0.032 | 0.136 | 0.205 | ||
(0.086) | (0.090) | (0.095) | (0.123) | (0.538) | |||
Observations | 1,043 | 1,043 | 1,043 | 1,043 | 1,043 | ||
B: Females | |||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | 0.315** | −0.110 | −0.018 | 0.019 | −0.539 | ||
(0.126) | (0.136) | (0.108) | (0.150) | (0.967) | |||
Observations | 1,325 | 1,325 | 1,325 | 1,325 | 1,325 |
This table reports instrumental variable estimates using the flexible second-order polynomial described in the text. We control for mother's education, father's education, private school enrollment, age, income, and religion in all specifications (see notes in table 1 for variable definitions). All regressions also include cutoff and month of survey fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at 0.25 bins of the centered high school exit exam score level are reported in parentheses. Significant at 10%, 5%, and 1%.
Next, we examine the attendance of subjects relative to their classmates. In column 2, we construct an outcome variable that takes the value 1 if the subject attended classes less often than his or her classmates. We find that marginally admitted men are more likely to skip classes than their classmates in less selective colleges. This points toward weakened self-concept among men on account of their lower academic position in the college, potentially indicating higher mental or psychic costs of investing effort. Elsner and Isphording (2017) also find a similar effect in that students with lower ordinal rank are more likely to be absent from classes.
Subjects could also experience learning gains due to complementary investments in education in the form of external private tutorials and remedial classes. These can improve test scores independent of the college and peer environment. However, as shown in column 3 of table 5, we do not find any discontinuity in the probability of using external tutorials for either males or females.
Heterogeneous Returns to College Quality: By College Ranks
. | . | Economic Preferences . | Personality Traits . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | University . | . | . | Risk . | . | . | . | Emotional . | Openness to . |
. | Exam Score . | Competitiveness . | Overconfidence . | Preference . | Extraversion . | Agreeableness . | Conscientiousness . | Stability . | Experience . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . | (9) . |
A: Men in Rank 1 | |||||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | −0.408 | −0.461 | −0.351*** | 0.275 | −0.341 | −0.016 | −0.694** | −0.160 | −0.427** |
(2.991) | (0.293) | (0.098) | (0.260) | (0.329) | (0.235) | (0.284) | (0.164) | (0.203) | |
Observations | 306 | 310 | 307 | 309 | 305 | 303 | 308 | 304 | 304 |
B: Women in Rank 1 | |||||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | 1.473 | 0.021 | −0.292* | 0.467** | −0.356* | −0.234 | 0.166 | 0.051 | −0.219 |
(1.473) | (0.189) | (0.168) | (0.190) | (0.213) | (0.197) | (0.299) | (0.395) | (0.266) | |
Observations | 494 | 497 | 492 | 497 | 493 | 493 | 494 | 494 | 492 |
C: Men Excluding Rank 1 Cutoffs | |||||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | −3.868 | 0.452 | 0.641 | −1.031 | −0.765** | −0.056 | −0.299 | 0.637 | 0.416 |
(4.397) | (0.610) | (0.539) | (0.663) | (0.361) | (0.327) | (0.437) | (0.648) | (0.388) | |
Observations | 724 | 733 | 728 | 729 | 716 | 710 | 721 | 714 | 714 |
D: Women Excluding Rank 1 Cutoffs | |||||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | 6.380 | 0.779 | −1.464 | 1.633** | 0.358 | 1.342 | −0.060 | 1.527 | 0.749 |
(4.826) | (0.573) | (1.105) | (0.804) | (0.791) | (1.123) | (0.570) | (1.207) | (1.245) | |
Observations | 822 | 825 | 808 | 824 | 817 | 812 | 817 | 817 | 818 |
. | . | Economic Preferences . | Personality Traits . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | University . | . | . | Risk . | . | . | . | Emotional . | Openness to . |
. | Exam Score . | Competitiveness . | Overconfidence . | Preference . | Extraversion . | Agreeableness . | Conscientiousness . | Stability . | Experience . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . | (9) . |
A: Men in Rank 1 | |||||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | −0.408 | −0.461 | −0.351*** | 0.275 | −0.341 | −0.016 | −0.694** | −0.160 | −0.427** |
(2.991) | (0.293) | (0.098) | (0.260) | (0.329) | (0.235) | (0.284) | (0.164) | (0.203) | |
Observations | 306 | 310 | 307 | 309 | 305 | 303 | 308 | 304 | 304 |
B: Women in Rank 1 | |||||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | 1.473 | 0.021 | −0.292* | 0.467** | −0.356* | −0.234 | 0.166 | 0.051 | −0.219 |
(1.473) | (0.189) | (0.168) | (0.190) | (0.213) | (0.197) | (0.299) | (0.395) | (0.266) | |
Observations | 494 | 497 | 492 | 497 | 493 | 493 | 494 | 494 | 492 |
C: Men Excluding Rank 1 Cutoffs | |||||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | −3.868 | 0.452 | 0.641 | −1.031 | −0.765** | −0.056 | −0.299 | 0.637 | 0.416 |
(4.397) | (0.610) | (0.539) | (0.663) | (0.361) | (0.327) | (0.437) | (0.648) | (0.388) | |
Observations | 724 | 733 | 728 | 729 | 716 | 710 | 721 | 714 | 714 |
D: Women Excluding Rank 1 Cutoffs | |||||||||
Enrolled in a selective college | 6.380 | 0.779 | −1.464 | 1.633** | 0.358 | 1.342 | −0.060 | 1.527 | 0.749 |
(4.826) | (0.573) | (1.105) | (0.804) | (0.791) | (1.123) | (0.570) | (1.207) | (1.245) | |
Observations | 822 | 825 | 808 | 824 | 817 | 812 | 817 | 817 | 818 |
This table reports instrumental variable estimates using the flexible second-order polynomial described in the text. We control for mother's education, father's education, private school enrollment, age, income, and religion in all specifications (see notes in table 1 for variable definitions). All regressions also include cutoff and month of survey fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at 0.25 bins of the centered high school exit exam score level are reported in parentheses. Significant at 10%, 5%, and 1%.
Due to multicollinearity, estimates reported in panel A are from flexible linear regressions.
Differences in indicators of teacher quality and presence could also matter for students' academic and nonacademic outcomes (Hoffmann & Oreopoulos, 2009; Jackson, 2018). As a measure of teacher presence, we asked students if teachers frequently cancelled classes. Results in column 4 show no discontinuity in the probability of classes being cancelled. Finally, results in column 5 indicate that the student-teacher ratio, an additional measure of teaching quality, also does not vary around the cutoff.
Finally, there might be unobserved differences across colleges in student-teacher interactions (such as informal in-class tests and levels of teacher attention and feedback) that may affect students' perception about their ability and rank. It is difficult to get information on these nuanced student-teacher interactions. Even if we assume these to be more prevalent in more selective colleges, it is not clear if the feedback reaffirms or mitigates students' concerns about relative rank. Thus, the net effect of such unobserved student-teacher interactions is ambiguous.
C. Robustness
In this section, we discuss a number of robustness checks. A crucial concern relates to sample selection bias such that applicants who narrowly fail to get admitted into selective colleges in DU may withdraw from DU to seek admission in other non-DU colleges or universities instead of taking admission in a less selective DU college. Thus, those who remain and choose a lower-ranking college in DU may be systematically different in terms of their behavior and socioemotional skills from those who exit from DU, inducing selection into the comparison group. In the absence of data on applications, which could have plausibly allowed us to identify such attrition during the admissions process (i.e., discouraged applicants at the margin), we surveyed 298 grade 12 students across eleven schools in New Delhi in 2019 who were on the verge of entry into higher education and collected information on their intentions for higher education such as colleges and universities, they are interested in applying to and attending, the Big Five traits, and background characteristics. We use this survey to conduct bounding exercises.
We find DU to be the top choice for an overwhelming share (93.3%) of the high school sample. Among these students who intend to apply to DU (our pool of potential applicants to DU), only 4% are potential attritors, that is, they state that if they do not get admission into the top-rank colleges, they will also decline admissions to lower-ranking DU colleges and seek admission elsewhere. Importantly, we find that the decisions to not apply to DU and to exit DU in the event of not getting into their preferred college are not correlated with any of the Big Five personality traits (see table A7 in the online appendix).
Nevertheless, we construct bounds for our treatment effects by modifying the procedure of Lee (2009) in the RD context. To construct the lower (upper) bounds on the treatment, we trim the top (bottom) 4% of the dependent variable in the treatment colleges and re-run our main regressions. These results are reported in online appendix tables A8 and A9 for men and women respectively. Our estimated treatment effects calibrated using the 4% attrition rate in the school survey are similar to the main results reported in table 4.25
The second concern relates to the possibility of type I error that increases with the number of outcomes tested. We use the method in Anderson (2008) to correct the standard errors for multiple hypotheses testing by families of outcomes. Our results are largely robust to this correction, and the sharpened q-values are reported in brackets in table 4.
Third, the presence of differential participation in our study around the cutoff would bias our estimates. Using administrative data on class sizes obtained under the Right to Information Act, we calculate the share of students who participated in our study. The average participation rate is 58% in our sample. We find no evidence of differential participation around the cutoff, thereby alleviating participation-related selection concerns (table A10 in the online appendix).
Fourth, students who move across colleges during the admissions process could be systematically different from those who could have potentially moved, but did not, that is, those with high school exit exam scores exceeding the required cutoff but currently enrolled in a comparison college, raising selection-related concerns. We find no difference between movers and potential movers in terms of the predetermined characteristics, with movers being negligibly older (table A11 in the online appendix), attenuating the aforementioned concerns.
Fifth, while we have some differences in sample sizes across regressions in table 4 due to nonresponse (in the range of 0.1% to 2% across all outcomes), our results are robust to limiting the sample to those respondents for whom we have data on all the outcomes (see table A12 in the online appendix).26
Sixth, we show that the LATE estimates reported earlier in table 4 are robust to (i) excluding the predetermined controls, (ii) using triangular weights that assign greater weights to observations closer to the cutoff instead of rectangular weights, and (iii) using outcome-specific optimal bandwidths as prescribed by Calonico, Cattaneo, and Titiunik (2014) (see tables A14 and A15 in the online appendix).
Next, another concern could be that the pools of applicants might have been different across treatment and comparison colleges during the admissions process. In the survey, we also collected data on the colleges students had applied to. We provided students with a list of seventeen colleges (of which fifteen were our sample colleges) and asked them to indicate all colleges they had applied to. While this may be subject to recall bias since at least two years had elapsed since admission, we use these data in the following manner. We construct a variable applicant that takes a value 1 for all students currently enrolled in treatment colleges as well as for any student from the comparison college who also applied to the treatment college, and 0 otherwise. We find that 87.6% of individuals enrolled in the comparison colleges had also applied to the treatment colleges. Our main results in table 4 are robust to limiting the sample to these “applicants” (table A16 in the online appendix).
Finally, in estimating the returns to college quality, we also implicitly assume that students prefer being in a more selective college to a less selective one. We now show that our results are largely robust to relaxing this assumption. In the survey, we asked students to rank a subset of the sample colleges as they would have at the time of admission. We use these data in the following way. While constructing each of our RD samples, we limit our sample to students who strictly rank all the treated colleges higher than the comparison colleges and do not rank any of the comparison colleges at least as high as any of the treated colleges. While the sample now is limited and there is bound to be some recall error, we find that the effects on most economic preferences and personality traits continue to hold (table A17 in the online appendix).
D. Heterogeneity
The existing literature has mainly studied effects of enrollment in top educational institutions (Abdulkadiroğlu et al., 2014; Hoekstra, 2009) or average effects of enrolling in relatively more selective institutions using data from a range of institutions (Jackson, 2010; Lucas & Mbiti, 2014: Pop-Eleches & Urquiola, 2013). However, returns to educational quality may be nonlinear and vary across the quality distribution. For example, Hoekstra et al. (2018) examine schools of varying selectivity in China and find effects stemming from enrollment present in only the most elite schools.
In a similar vein, in table 6 we examine if behavioral responses to college and peer environments differ depending on how selective the college is. For this purpose, we reestimate our regressions separately examining the effect of enrolling in a rank 1 (most selective) colleges in panels A and B, and the effects of enrolling in ranks 2 and 3 (less selective) colleges, that is, excluding rank 1 college cutoffs in panels C and D. The returns to college quality may vary across these two samples as the scope for improvement based on peer learning may be lower in rank 1 colleges. Further, the adverse effects of lower relative rank on academic self-concept may be more acutely felt in the more selective colleges.
We find that enrolling in a rank 1 college reduces conscientiousness, openness to experience, and overconfidence among marginally admitted males and increases risk taking and reduces overconfidence and extraversion for women. In contrast, we find that excluding rank 1 college cutoffs only reduces extraversion for men and increases risk taking among women. Overall, the results suggest that men are more likely to be susceptible to relative rank concerns in the most selective colleges, which results in negative effects on personality and behavior reported in panel A compared to panel C, table 6. On the other hand, for women, the results in panels B and D remain largely similar. However, these results should be interpreted with some caution as we lack the statistical power to conduct a finer analysis.
V. Conclusion
The existing empirical work on the returns to college quality has largely focused on test scores as outcomes of human capital and generated mixed evidence. Scant attention has been paid to underlying economic preferences and socioemotional traits—facets of human capital that recent research has documented as being important for one's economic progress.
In this paper, our aim has been to fill this critical gap by examining the effects of college selectivity on cognitive, behavioral, and socioemotional outcomes, using data collected from a large sample of students at a leading Indian university. Exploiting the variation in college admission cutoffs, we compare students just above the cutoff with those just below the cutoff to determine the causal impact of enrollment in a selective college, where they are surrounded by relatively high-achieving peers and have a lower relative rank in their peer group. We find that marginally admitted female students in more selective colleges experience improvements in scores on standardized university exams. In terms of behavior and personality, we find that women just above the cutoff become less risk averse and less overconfident. On the other hand, men in these colleges experience declines in extraversion and conscientiousness, pointing toward a weakened self-concept due to a lower relative rank in their peer group, capturing the small fish in a big pond effect. Further, we are also able to show that variations in college qualities stem mainly from variations in peer qualities (and rank) with no differences in teacher presence or student-teacher ratios around the cutoff.
Some caveats remain. First, while our study shows that the effects of selective colleges are not unequivocally positive for the outcomes we consider in the short run, it is important to bear in mind that in the long run, elite colleges are still likely to lead to higher wages, access to well-connected alumni networks, and better marriage prospects. Second, it is possible that exposure to being in a selective college may affect some socioemotional skills only in the long run, such that our effects are underestimated. Third, while our study does not encompass the entire population of DU students, to the extent the admissions process is similar to that for economics and commerce, our overall framework on peer quality and rank concerns should matter in a similar way for other disciplines as well. However, it should be noted that as DU is one of the premier universities in India, its students are not representative of the average Indian college student. Although this study is unable to comment on the long-run effects on personality traits and labor market outcomes, it should encourage follow-up work that can can shed light on longer-term impacts of such peer effects.
Notes
That personality is malleable in adolescence and young adulthood is now well accepted (Borghans et al., 2008; Specht, Egloff, & Schmukle, 2011). While cognitive ability, typically measured by IQ, is relatively stable after age 10, there is evidence that negative and positive experiences can have an impact on behavior and personality (Chuang & Schechter, 2015; Schurer, Kassenboehmer, & Leung, 2018). A recent literature finds that socioemotional skills measured after varying lengths of program exposure (8–36 months), can in fact be shaped by soft skills interventions (Acevedo et al., 2017; Adhvaryu, Kala, & Nyshadham, 2018; Campos et al., 2017).
The evidence on rank effects being more prevalent in more heterogeneous student ability environments is not conclusive. In the education psychology literature, Marsh et al. (2008) show that rank concerns are likely to prevail across different settings, and even in groups of gifted students. In economics, Elsner and Isphording (2017) find that ordinal rank concerns hold in cohorts with both high and low variance in ability. These results could also be linked to the literature on the effect of heterogeneity in peer ability on student achievement and effort, and the findings appear mixed. For example, Carrell, Sacerdote, and West (2013) and Booij, Leuven, and Oosterbeek (2017) find student achievement to be higher in low-variance peer ability settings. Lyle (2009) finds that high variance in peer ability increases student achievement.
This could also explain the mixed evidence on peer effects in education with some studies finding positive peer effects and others documenting nonlinear or no effects (Sacerdote, 2011).
These preferences and traits have been identified to explain a range of labor market outcomes. Competitiveness can explain gender gaps in wages (Niederle & Vesterlund, 2007). Overconfidence affects entrepreneurial entry (Koellinger, Minniti, & Schade, 2007). Recent work from developing countries also shows a link between these skills and indicators of labor force participation, performance, and skill accumulation (Dasgupta et al., 2015; Nordman, Sarr, & Sharma, 2019; Sharma & Tarp, 2018). Finally, a spate of recent papers also finds that soft skills embedded training programs can influence labor market performance (through effects on socioemotional traits). Adhvaryu et al. (2018) find an on-the-job soft skills training program for Indian female garment workers to have led to gains in worker productivity, possibly through improvements in extraversion and forward-looking behavior. Acevedo et al. (2017) find that a soft skills embedded vocational training resulted in higher levels of soft skills and higher employment for women in the Dominican Republic. Campos et al. (2017) find that a psychology-based personal initiative program for microenterprise owners in Togo led to higher profits and adoption of business practices.
In India, after a common high-stakes exam in grade 10, in the last two years of high school, students select into one of the following academic tracks, each of which has four subjects and a language: science, commerce, and humanities. At the end of grade 12, they take the high school exit exam, which varies by track. College admissions often require a certain high school track. For example, students applying for undergraduate degrees in science should have had a science track. Commerce and economics disciplines require applicants to have studied mathematics in their high school tracks.
These cutoffs are publicly available at http://www.du.ac.in/index.php?id=664.
As cutoffs drop between admission rounds, it is possible for students to move up to colleges where they are now eligible. In our sample, 26.5% of the students switched colleges during the admission process, of whom 94% moved to a more selective college. We discuss this further in section IVC.
The remaining 21 colleges offer only specialized disciplines such as pharmacy, nursing, homeopathy, physical and sports education, and art.
A concern with focusing on economics and commerce may be that of discipline-specific, gender-based selection effects. Based on data obtained under the Right to Information Act, we calculate the share of female students across all colleges within DU enrolled in the first year in 2011 in a variety of disciplines (table A1 in the online appendix). The share of women exceeds 50% in the arts disciplines and is just below 50% in the science disciplines. This is consistent with previous evidence in the literature on gender-based selection across disciplines (see Buser et al., 2014 and papers cited therein). Notably, we do not find the share of female students in economics and commerce to be outliers, implying that discipline-specific selection effects at the time of entry into DU are unlikely to be a pressing concern for our analysis.
The survey methodology is available at https://www.indiatoday.in/india/best-colleges/story/best-colleges-in-india-2012-methodology-105020-2012-06-08. 2011 rankings available at: https://www.indiatoday.in/bestcolleges/2012/compare-college/2011-commerce-arts. 2012 rankings at: https://www.indiatoday.in/bestcolleges/2012/compare-college/2012-commerce-arts.
NIRF 2019 rankings are available at https://www.nirfindia.org/2019/CollegeRanking.html.
Borker (2017) finds that 72% of DU students are from Delhi and live with their parents. In 2016, almost 80% of applicants to DU were from Delhi and the neighboring states of Uttar Pradesh and Haryana: https://www.hindustantimes.com/delhi/50-delhi-university-aspirants-from-delhi-this-year/story-oWvwZH76uFK7DpgWP0OlCP.html.
We conducted a survey of approximately 300 grade 12 students across eleven high schools in Delhi in 2019 and found that DU is the top choice for over 93.3% of them.
We implemented a pilot version of this game where forty students from DU had participated, and their performance is used for comparison in the tournament wage scheme.
Our measure of overconfidence falls in the category of overestimation (Moore & Healy, 2008). Our competition design as well as the nonincentivized belief elicitation is similar to Dasgupta et al. (2015, 2017), and Kamas and Preston (2012). Further, since we were already paying for the real effort task, we did not incentivize the belief elicitation in line with Karni and Safra (1995).
We also administered a ten-item Raven's (progressive) matrices test, which is acknowledged as a measure of fluid intelligence (e.g., see the review in Dean, Schilbach, & Schofield, 2019). We find a strong positive and significant relationship between performance on Raven's test and university exam scores, ruling out concerns about these exams reflecting rote-learning skills alone. See table A2 in the online appendix.
Similarly, we also have a few instances where students who are ineligible for a more selective college are admitted to that college. Overall, in the stacked sample used in the analysis, only 0.37% of the subjects who have a negative distance from the cutoff are enrolled in a more selective college, and approximately 8.85% of the subjects who have a positive distance from the cutoff are enrolled in a less selective college.
The main results are robust to two-way clustering of the standard errors at student and bin level, as in Cameron, Gelbach, and Miller (2011). Results are available from the authors upon request.
The student allocation mechanism in DU is different from the more commonly observed centralized mechanisms such as the Boston school choice mechanism (Abdulkadiroğlu et al., 2014), the student or college proposing deferred acceptance mechanisms, or the top trading cycle mechanism (Sönmez & Ünver, 2011), where students indicate preference rankings over disciplines and colleges and a central body allocates students.
According to the nationally representative India Human Development Survey of 2011–2012, the average yearly income for upper-caste households is approximately INR 180,000 (appropriate reference group for our analysis). This indicates that students in our sample belong to households with a relatively higher socioeconomic status, and thus are not representative of the overall population.
We also conducted the density test proposed by Cattaneo, Jansson, and Ma (2020) and do not reject the null hypothesis that the density is smooth around the cutoff (-value 0.13).
Note that this does not necessarily imply that those at the top of the distribution will also start overestimating their ability and become overconfident to the same extent. Therefore, conceptually it does not imply that there is a zero-sum game within a college for overconfidence.
Due to a modest sample size, some of our coefficients are imprecisely estimated and we are unable to reject the null of equality in coefficients between men and women. Gender differences are significant for outcomes related to risk preferences () and conscientiousness (), but not for university exam scores (), overconfidence (), and extraversion ().
Since attendance is self-reported, presence of random measurement error in this outcome variable is likely to bias the standard errors upward.
We thank the editor for this suggestion. We also conduct bounding exercises assuming 7%, 10%, and 15% attrition to examine the sensitivity of our estimates. As shown in online appendix tables A8 and A9, the lower bounds are statistically significant for all male and female outcomes at 7%, 10%, and 15% attrition rate (except for exam score for women). While we present both upper- and lower-bound estimates, the lower bounds may be more relevant for us if the “marginally disappointed” individuals (with higher cognitive ability, extraversion, conscientiousness, overconfidence, and risk) were more likely to seek out non-DU alternatives for college admission, creating sample selection in the comparison group.
We also find the probability of missing data on the outcomes is not systematic around the cutoff except for males' overconfidence (table A13 in the online appendix).
REFERENCES
Author notes
We thank Kehinde Ajayi, Felipe Barrera-Osorio, Leah Boustan, Matias Busso, Raissa Fabregas, Arya Gaduh, Maia Guell, Ingo Isphording, Asim Khwaja, David McKenzie, Abhijeet Singh, Bertil Tungodden, Lore Vandewalle, and three anonymous reviewers for useful feedback. We also thank seminar participants at Copenhagen, Choice Lab, UPenn, Columbia, Fordham, GeorgiaTech, Hunter, UConn, 3ie, Indian School of Business, Monash, Rutgers, Shiv Nadar, and conference participants at NEUDC, IGC-ISI India Conference, ASSA, Leuven, York, and Nordic Conference in Development Economics for comments. We are grateful to the staff at colleges of University of Delhi for lending their support. Neha Agarwal, Riju Bafna, Piyush Bhadani, Tanya Gupta, Aishwarya Joshi, Japneet Kaur, and Anshul Yadav provided excellent research assistance. We acknowledge support from Fordham University, International Growth Center–India Central, UNU-WIDER, and Newcastle University. These institutions had no involvement in study design, data collection, analysis, or interpretation. This paper was previously circulated as “Cognitive, Socioemotional and Behavioral Returns to College Quality.”
A supplemental appendix is available online at https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00966.