Abstract
Do firearm purchase delay laws reduce aggregate homicide levels? Using variation from a six-month countrywide gun demand shock in 2012/2013, we show that U.S. states with legislation preventing immediate handgun purchases experienced smaller increases in handgun sales. Our findings indicate that this is likely driven by comparatively lower purchases among impulsive consumers. We then demonstrate that states with purchase delays also witnessed comparatively 2% lower homicide rates during the same period. Further evidence shows that lower handgun sales coincided primarily with fewer impulsive assaults and points toward reduced acts of domestic violence.
I. Introduction
THE relationship between firearm ownership and criminal activity has been one of the most polarizing topics in U.S. politics over the past decades. Supporters of gun rights often claim that arming citizens will lead to decreases in crime, while supporters of gun control point to the high numbers of victims of gun-related violence. Fowler et al. (2015) report that 32,000 Americans are killed and another 67,000 injured by firearms every year. Based on their calculations, any policy measure effectively reducing these numbers would have the potential for welfare gains of almost $50 billion each year. Curbing gun violence was also the intention behind many of the 130 gun control policy measures that have been enacted so far across U.S. states (Siegel et al., 2017).
One such group of policy measures, targeted explicitly at preventing impulsive acts of gun violence, are firearm purchase delay laws. These measures, by now in place in fifteen U.S. states, create a temporal distance between the decision to buy a gun and its eventual receipt. Delays can last from two days up to six months and occur through mandatory waiting periods or bureaucratic hurdles associated with obtaining purchasing permits. Both measures provide gun buyers with a cooling-off period during which those with short-lived suicidal or homicidal intentions may reconsider their planned actions (Cook, 1978; Andrés & Hempstead, 2011). Since delay laws should also keep impulsive consumers without violent intentions from buying guns, they offer a unique avenue to investigate whether and how prevented firearm purchases by such individuals translate into reduced gun violence. However, such analysis would require a reasonably large shift in impulse purchases unrelated to local crime levels.
In this paper, we exploit one of the largest aggregate shocks to U.S. firearm demand to study the effects of handgun purchase delay laws. In a first step, we show that the existence of purchase delays led to a relative reduction in handgun sales during the six months after the 2012 presidential election and the shooting at Sandy Hook Elementary School. During this period, fear of more restrictive gun control legislation and higher perceived need for self-defense capabilities led to record sales of firearms across the entire United States (Vox, 2016; CNBC, 2012). We use a difference in differences (DiD) framework, comparing handgun sale background checks (BGCs) in states with handgun purchase delays to states without such delays during the six-month window of increased firearm demand. Our baseline results indicate that states with purchase delay laws witnessed a 7% to 8% relative decrease in handgun sales. Differences in gun popularity and other types of firearm legislation cannot explain these results.
Next, we present evidence suggesting that lower purchasing levels were indeed more likely driven by impulsive buyers. We start by analyzing Google search data and show that delay laws did not lead to comparatively lower public interest in buying firearms during the demand shock. Handgun purchase delay laws thus did not seem to affect intentions to buy firearms, but only whether consumers' interest translated into actual purchases. Using state variation in delay lengths, we also do not observe a relationship between our estimated effect size and delay length. For deliberate and exponentially discounting consumers, these should have been positively correlated since delays smoothly reduce the discounted net present value of owning a gun. This discontinuous impact of delay lengths on purchases lends further credibility to the presence of impulsive consumers.
In the second part of our analysis, we investigate the effect of delay laws on homicides. Using the same DiD framework, we find that counties in states with purchasing delays experienced a relative 2% decrease in overall homicide rates during the demand spike, which is entirely driven by homicides involving handguns. Our baseline estimate implies that about 200 lives could have been saved in the six-month period alone if handgun purchase delays had been in place in all U.S. states. An extensive set of robustness checks shows that our results are specific to the period of the demand hike and not driven by single states or the sample choice. Looking into the characteristics of the additional homicides in states without handgun purchase delays, we find evidence in line with the notion that gun ownership among impulsive buyers is associated with crimes of passion.1 For female victims, the evidence points toward instances of domestic violence, as the majority of additional female homicides occurred inside the victim's home and arose from an argument. The affected killings of males occurred mainly outside their homes but were similarly strongly related to arguments.
This study is related to three important streams of research. First, we add to the literature investigating the impact of firearm legislation and, in particular, purchase delays, on crime rates. Previous studies found either decreases (Rudolph et al., 2015; Edwards et al., 2018; Luca, Malhotra, & Poliquin, 2017) or zero effects (Ludwig & Cook, 2000) on violent crime or homicides. As the adoption of firearm purchase delay laws may not be exogenous and law changes can be anticipated by prospective gun buyers, our paper substantially advances this literature by providing novel and credible identification through exploiting a sudden and unanticipated demand shock in conjunction with preexisting delay laws.2 We also provide suggestive evidence that our empirical setup mainly picks up the behavior of impulsive consumers without violent intentions and offers insights into the types of homicides prevented through purchase delays.
Second, we contribute to the literature in economics, criminology, and public health, studying the impact of firearm ownership on violent crime. The majority of studies find a positive relationship (Cook & Ludwig, 2006; Duggan, 2001; Miller, Azrael, & Hemenway, 2002; Miller, Hemenway, & Azrael, 2007; Siegel, Ross, & King, 2013). Some studies, however, also report no effect (Duggan, Hjalmarsson, & Jacob, 2011; Moody & Marvell, 2005; Kovandzic, Schaffer, & Kleck, 2013; Lang, 2016). A recent paper by Levine and McKnight (2017) shows with a different identification strategy that elevated gun exposure after the Sandy Hook shooting translated into higher rates of firearm-related accidents.3 We confirm the positive link between gun ownership and homicides found in previous studies but are the first to look specifically into firearm homicide characteristics and highlight the role of impulsiveness.
Third, our evaluation of gun purchase delay laws contributes to the growing literature analyzing how policies can mitigate the consequences of behavioral biases (overviews are provided in Chetty, 2015; Bernheim & Taubinsky, 2018). To the best of our knowledge, we are the first to study impulsive behavior in the context of gun ownership. Few other studies at the intersection between behavioral economics and economics of crime have also linked impulsiveness to criminal activity and acts of violence (Dahl & DellaVigna, 2009; Card & Dahl, 2011; Heller et al., 2017). We advance this literature by providing the first study to establish a link between firearm availability and the fatal consequences of impulsive behavior.
II. Background
A. Purchase Delay Laws in the United States
The Second Amendment to the U.S. Constitution protects the fundamental right of citizens to keep and bear arms. Federal, state, and local governments, however, have enacted laws making it harder and more cumbersome for citizens to acquire firearms. On the federal level, two crucial pieces of legislation are the Gun Control Act of 1968 and the Brady Handgun Violence Prevention Act. The Gun Control Act requires all professional gun dealers to have a Federal Firearms License (FFL). Only they can engage in interstate trade of handguns, are granted access to firearm wholesalers, and can receive firearms by mail. The Brady Act of November 1993 mandated BGCs for all gun purchases through FFL dealers and imposed a five-day waiting period to conduct these checks. Upon successful lobbying by the National Rifle Association (NRA), these waiting periods were set to expire when the FBI's National Instant Criminal Background Check System (NICS) was introduced in 1998. Since then, the NICS handles all BGCs related to the sales of firearms. While there is comparatively little regulation on gun ownership at the federal level, there is substantial heterogeneity in restrictions imposed by U.S. states. Constraints on private firearm ownership at the state level predominantly attempt to either prohibit potentially dangerous people such as convicted felons from acquiring guns or restrict the usefulness of firearms for unlawful purposes independent of the buyer.
In this study, we focus on handguns since these, unlike long guns, have to be purchased in the state of residence, are a popular choice for self-defense, can be carried concealed, and are used in homicides substantially more often than long guns (Federal Bureau of Investigation, 2016). Our analyses utilize two types of delays between the decision to purchase and the moment the handgun is actually transferred. The first one is mandatory waiting periods. While the initial aim of waiting periods in the Brady Act was to give law enforcement agencies enough time to conduct BGCs, they also provide a cooling-off period and can thus help to prevent impulsive acts of violence (Cook, 1978; Andrés & Hempstead, 2011). In practice, buyers will perform a purchase (pass a NICS BGC and pay for the chosen gun) but can receive their handgun only after the waiting period has elapsed. The second measure is state requirements for licenses to lawfully possess or buy a handgun. Due to bureaucratic hurdles in the licensing process, these impose a de facto waiting time. Prospective buyers have to request the permit at a local authority (e.g., a sheriff's office), pass a NICS BGC, and pay the associated fee.4 Only after the permit has been processed and issued can they proceed with the purchase at their local dealer (usually without a renewed BGC).
In order to accurately determine the presence of delay laws and minimize misclassification, we utilize several sources and apply a rigorous coding procedure outlined with all details in appendix section A.1. The final state classification is reported in appendix table 27, which shows that during the period of our study, from November 2009 to October 2013, fifteen states and the District of Columbia had adopted some form of delay laws throughout. Nine states (California, Florida, Hawaii, Illinois, Maryland, Minnesota, New Jersey, Rhode Island, Wisconsin) and the District of Columbia had imposed mandatory waiting periods on handgun purchases.5 Connecticut, Hawaii, Illinois, Maryland, Massachusetts, New Jersey, New York, Nebraska, North Carolina, and Rhode Island all require a purchasing permit during the period of our study. Michigan abolished its handgun permit requirement in December 2012 and is thus the only state switching its delay legislation during our study period. For the remainder of this paper, we refer to a state that implemented a mandatory waiting period, required a purchasing permit, or both, as a Delay state.6 We refer to all other states as NoDelay states.
B. The Firearm Demand Shock of 2012/2013
Our analysis focuses on the firearm demand spike after the reelection of President Obama in November 2012 and the Sandy Hook shooting in December 2012. We decided on these two particular events to study the impact of delay laws on gun sales and homicides for two main reasons. First, these events then marked the largest hike in handgun sales since background data were collected in 1999. Such a strong shock is required in order to detect any statistically significant effects on firearm purchases and homicides. Second, unlike the numerous later shootings that grabbed nationwide attention, our setup features a pretreatment period uncontaminated by other events, which is essential to accurately account for the seasonal nature of the data. In the following, we briefly describe the two events and the firearm demand hike of 2012/2013.
In the presidential election on November 6, 2012, President Barack Obama ran for a second term against Republican candidate Mitt Romney. While Romney took a more liberal position toward gun rights and was endorsed by the NRA, President Obama favored stricter gun control laws. In October 2012, almost all polls showed the race as within the margin of error, and President Obama's victory came so unexpectedly for Romney on election night that he had not even prepared a concession speech as internal polls had shown him winning (International Business Times, 2012). Similar to President Obama's first election in 2008, gun sales increased after his reelection, but this time with considerably larger magnitude (CNN, 2008; CNN Money, 2012; Depetris-Chauvin, 2015). This was likely because the president had started to speak more openly about favoring increased gun control measures in the wake of recent mass shootings, especially the one at a movie theater in Aurora, Colorado, in July 2012.
About a month later, on December 14, 2012, 20-year-old Adam Lanza of Newtown, Connecticut, first shot and killed his mother at their home before driving to Sandy Hook Elementary School. There he shot and killed 6 school employees and 20 students aged 6 to 7 years. Lanza committed suicide shortly after the first law enforcement officers arrived at the scene. His motives are still not fully understood, but it has been suggested that he had a history of mental illness (New Yorker, 2014). The massacre was the deadliest ever U.S. school shooting and the third deadliest mass shooting in U.S. history at the time. This and the fact that most of the victims were defenseless children sparked a renewed and unprecedented debate about gun control in the United States.
A few days after the shooting, President Barack Obama announced that he would make gun control a central issue of his second term and quickly assembled a gun violence task force led by Vice President Joe Biden to collect ideas on how to curb gun violence and prevent future mass shootings. The task force presented their suggestions to President Obama in January 2013, who announced he would implement twenty-three executive actions. These were aimed at expanding BGCs, addressing mental health issues and insurance coverage of treatment, as well as enhancing safety measures for schools and law enforcement officers responding to active shooter situations. Additionally, the task force proposed twelve congressional actions, including renewing the Federal Assault Weapons Ban, expanding criminal BGCs to private transactions, banning high-capacity magazines, and increasing funds for law enforcement agencies.
The proposals were met by fierce opposition from the NRA and some Republican legislators. At the end of January 2013, Senator Dianne Feinstein (D) introduced a bill to reinstate the Federal Assault Weapons Ban. While the bill passed the Senate Judiciary Committee in March 2013, it eventually was struck down on April 17, 2013, by the Senate, 40-60, with all but one Republican and some Democrats opposing the bill. A bipartisan bill to be voted on that same day, introduced by Senators Joe Manchin (D) and Pat Toomey (R), aimed at introducing universal BGCs, also failed to find the necessary three-fifths majority with 54-46, leaving federal legislation eventually unaffected.
III. Data
A. Handgun Purchases
One of the main challenges in our analysis is the absence of a central database of gun owners and firearm sales. To overcome this, researchers have often turned to proxy variables from surveys, vital statistics, crime data, and gun magazine subscriptions. While some of these indicators performed well in cross-sectional analyses, they have been found unsuitable for tracking gun ownership over time (Kleck, 2004). Since November 1998, federal law dictates that an electronic NICS BGC be carried out for every firearm transaction through an FFL dealer. These publicly available data have the merit of being comparable across time, providing high coverage at a monthly frequency, and distinguishes among different types of transactions and firearms. The main variable in the first part of our analysis is NICS BGCs for handgun sales in a given state between November 2010 and October 2013, divided by the 2010 population in 100,000. In order to interpret our results as semi-elasticities and reduce the influence of outliers while keeping zero observations, we apply the inverse hyperbolic sine (IHS) transformation instead of taking natural logarithms.7
As pointed out in recent studies, the NICS data also exhibit significant drawbacks (Lang, 2013, 2016; Levine & McKnight, 2017). First, these data can only measure flows of weapons but do not allow inferring the stock of firearms or ownership levels. Second, flows might be substantially understated as about 22% of firearm sales are between private parties and occur in states that do not require BGCs for private transactions (Miller, Hepburn, & Azrael, 2017). Third, a BGC can occur for the purchase of multiple weapons, as well as an exchange of an old for a new firearm. Fourth, the data do not distinguish between approved and rejected BGCs, and even an approved check does not guarantee the sale of a firearm. Finally, some states require a BGC for a concealed carry permit application but not for a handgun purchase itself. Other states are running regular or irregular rechecks on existing permit holders and thereby inflate the counts or produce outliers.
We believe that our setup mitigates some of these problems. The anecdotes that we have noted, as well as findings from California by Studdert et al. (2017), indicate that many handgun purchases during the demand shock in late 2012 were made by new gun owners. With few sales to preexisting gun owners, this should strengthen the correlation between handgun sale BGCs and changes in firearm ownership. Sales outside the NICS through private transactions and particularly gun shows are a concern but would only invalidate our results if they were more common in NoDelay states during the sales hike. Since many consumers were first-time buyers, we deem it more likely they were buying from a regular FFL dealer than privately.8 Multiple purchases are unproblematic given our interest in the extensive margin of gun ownership. A boost in exchanges of old for new guns in Delay states could also overstate increases in firearm ownership in those states. Since the likelihood of such exchanges should be correlated with preexisting levels of gun ownership, we can control for this concern in additional robustness checks. Furthermore, work by Mueller and Frandsen (2017) has shown that only about 1.5% of BGCs across the United States are actually rejected, which severely limits the impact of this potential source of error. There is also no strong indication that the demand shock affected the rejection probability asymmetrically across Delay and NoDelay states. Finally, we add BGCs for permits to our measure of handgun sales to capture cases where buyers obtain a permit to purchase a handgun.9
A closer investigation of the NICS data revealed several outliers and reporting issues. We therefore removed Hawaii, Illinois, Kentucky, Massachusetts, Pennsylvania, and Utah, as well as parts of the series for Iowa, Maryland, and Wisconsin, from the sample.10 We also drop Connecticut and Michigan. Connecticut was host to the Sandy Hook shooting and thus may have potentially experienced lower gun sales after the shooting due to social pressure or psychological effects on residents. Michigan switched treatment status during our period of observation from requiring a permit to not requiring a permit. Performing the steps above yields our baseline sample consisting of 43 U.S. states for investigating the effect of delay laws on handgun sales (BL1). While we prefer this restricted sample for our NICS analysis, robustness checks for our main results show that alternative (and less restrictive) sample definitions generate qualitatively similar results.
B. Homicide and Mortality
In order to cross-validate our results and delve deeper into homicide circumstances, we also use the Supplementary Homicide Reports (SHR) series from the UCR data, bearing in mind the limitations of the data. These reports are compiled from voluntary submissions by individual law enforcement agencies to the FBI and contain detailed information such as demographics of victim and offender, the type of weapon used, as well as murder circumstances (e.g., argument or gang-related crime). We clean the SHR data following the procedure described in appendix section A.4 and then collapse observations into a balanced monthly panel for 2,091 counties. Counts are normalized using the aggregate population in 100,000 covered by the reporting agencies within a specific county in 2010. Both UCR and NVSS crime rates are converted into logs using the same IHS transformation as for the NICS data.
C. Gun Interest and Controls
To assess whether consumers in states with and without handgun purchase delays have similar preferences, one needs to separate initial intentions to buy handguns from actual purchases. While we use NICS data to measure the latter, we rely on Internet search data from Google Trends to proxy for people's intention to purchase firearms. We focus on searches for the term “gun store,” which prior research has shown to be a good predictor of firearm purchasing intentions (Scott & Varian, 2014). Since the search data come in relative numbers, we adopt a technique similar to that used by Durante and Zhuravskaya (2018) to construct a state-level panel of monthly Google searches for “gun store.”12
In addition, we use several control variables to account for potential confounders as well as differences in socioeconomic characteristics across counties and states. Our core set of covariates includes the log of population, the shares of the population living in rural areas and below the poverty line, as well as the percentages of Black and Hispanic inhabitants. All variables were obtained from the 2010 U.S. Decennial Census at the county level (and aggregated for state-level analyses). In addition, we collected state-level data on the percentage of households with Internet access from the 2010 American Community Survey, which we include in regressions using Google search data. In selecting these control variables, we broadly followed the choices made in prior studies that have investigated the relationship between firearm prevalence and crime (Cook & Ludwig, 2006; Duggan, 2001). Further variables used only for robustness checks, such as measures of gun popularity, are introduced and explained where appropriate.13
IV. Empirical Strategy
A. Difference-in-Differences Approach
We use equation (1) to estimate the effect of the demand surge on handgun sales in Delay over NoDelay states. Equation (2) is effectively the county-level analog of equation (1) but instead uses homicide rates as outcome variables. In these equations, the specific effect of delay laws during the demand shock captured via can be regarded as a shifter for new gun owners. is a dummy variable for states with delay laws as described in section IIA and summarized in appendix table 27: California, Florida, Hawaii, Illinois, Iowa, Maryland, Massachusetts, Minnesota, Nebraska, New Jersey, New York, North Carolina, Rhode Island, Wisconsin, and the District of Columbia. is a dummy for time periods starting with President Obama's reelection in November 2012 and ending after April 2013 when the proposals for a renewed assault weapons ban and universal BGCs were defeated in the U.S. Senate. Our primary coefficient of interest is and captures the average proportionate difference in HandgunSales and Homicides between Delay and NoDelay states during the demand shock. We also include a second interaction using the time dummy for May 2013 to October 2013 to investigate effects beyond the initial six months. This also allows testing whether Delay states experience comparatively fewer handgun purchases over the entire time period or if this is compensated by more sales later.
Apart from time fixed-effects , the DiD regressions also allow for location-specific linear trends and to account for the possibility that some areas may deviate from general trends in BGCs and homicides. Furthermore, our regression models each also feature a set of control variables . We avoid concerns about “bad controls” by using interactions of predetermined, time-invariant factors and time fixed effects. The variables included in this way are % Hispanic, % Black, % rural, the log of population, and % poverty. denotes the residual. The standard errors used for inference are clustered by state as the level of treatment assignment to account for serial correlation in the error terms. Regressions are weighted by the state/county population to reduce the impact of less densely populated areas and to obtain U.S.-wide average effects.14
A potential alternative to our approach would be to estimate a gun owner-homicide elasticity using as an instrument. Our preference for the somewhat cruder reduced-form relationship stems from two factors. The first is the limitations of the NICS data discussed above. BGCs do not allow drawing direct inference on changes in the existing population of gun owners, making an elasticity hardly comparable to other studies. This concern is compounded by issues of measurement error, as not all BGCs lead to gun purchases and not all purchases are reflected in the BGC counts. Our second concern is that we do not expect the effect of gun owners on homicides to be overly large since the vast majority of gun owners are law-abiding citizens (Fabio et al., 2016). To precisely estimate such a small effect, one would need a fairly large sample at the county level for which, however, no NICS data exist. We thus estimate the raw effect of handgun purchase frictions on sales and homicide rates during the demand shock but do not pin down a precise elasticity given the absence of reliable panel data on firearm ownership.
B. Validity of Identifying Assumptions
The second prerequisite is the absence of correlated shocks—that is, other events coinciding with the demand hike and being positively (negatively) correlated with the existence of delay laws but negatively (positively) with BGCs and homicide rates. As argued above, the outcome of the 2012 election, as well as the timing of the Sandy Hook shooting, are unrelated to any relevant outcome variables and were arguably the most notable events at that time. We tackle the remaining concerns in three ways: First, all regressions control for sociodemographic factors known to be correlated with both gun ownership and crime. Second, we corroborate the role of delay laws by running horse race regressions where we add interactions of time dummies with potential confounders related to political leanings, as well as preferences for and supply of firearms. Finally, in section VC, we use Google search data to show that the divergence in gun sales after the shock does not coincide with a similar divergence in the interest to purchase a firearm.
V. The Effect of Delay Laws on Firearm Purchases
A. Results
In table 1, we estimate the differential impact of the six-month demand hike in Delay states on our handgun sale measure as well as total and nonhandgun sale BGCs per capita. The main coefficient of interest is from equation (1), which represents the percentage difference of the sales rate response to the demand shock in Delay states compared to NoDelay states. Column 1 shows a significant negative effect in the first six months after the presidential election and a positive nonsignificant effect in the second period. This potential postponement effect, however, disappears when adding controls in column 2, while the coefficient for the Post1 period remains marginally significant. After adding state-specific linear time trends in column 3 and accounting for potential pretrends, the estimate for gains precision while decreases further. A very likely explanation for this result would be that this specification reduces noise from diverging trends in smaller states without significantly influencing the overall (weighted) coefficient.
. | Log of BGCs per 100,000 Inhabitants . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Handgun Sale . | Total . | Other . | ||||
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . |
Delay Post1 | −0.112*** | −0.081* | −0.073** | −0.036 | −0.028 | 0.016 | 0.026 |
(0.041) | (0.045) | (0.033) | (0.028) | (0.024) | (0.053) | (0.049) | |
Delay Post2 | 0.057 | 0.008 | 0.005 | 0.048 | 0.053 | 0.113 | 0.127 |
(0.062) | (0.066) | (0.086) | (0.054) | (0.062) | (0.097) | (0.095) | |
Year-Month FE | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Controls | N | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y |
State Trends | N | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y |
States | 43 | 43 | 43 | 43 | 43 | 43 | 43 |
Observations | 1,516 | 1,516 | 1,516 | 1,516 | 1,516 | 1,516 | 1,516 |
0.446 | 0.538 | 0.591 | 0.685 | 0.721 | 0.676 | 0.756 |
. | Log of BGCs per 100,000 Inhabitants . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Handgun Sale . | Total . | Other . | ||||
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . |
Delay Post1 | −0.112*** | −0.081* | −0.073** | −0.036 | −0.028 | 0.016 | 0.026 |
(0.041) | (0.045) | (0.033) | (0.028) | (0.024) | (0.053) | (0.049) | |
Delay Post2 | 0.057 | 0.008 | 0.005 | 0.048 | 0.053 | 0.113 | 0.127 |
(0.062) | (0.066) | (0.086) | (0.054) | (0.062) | (0.097) | (0.095) | |
Year-Month FE | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Controls | N | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y |
State Trends | N | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y |
States | 43 | 43 | 43 | 43 | 43 | 43 | 43 |
Observations | 1,516 | 1,516 | 1,516 | 1,516 | 1,516 | 1,516 | 1,516 |
0.446 | 0.538 | 0.591 | 0.685 | 0.721 | 0.676 | 0.756 |
Observations are at the state-month level. The sample period is November 2010 until October 2013, an asymmetric 36-month window two years before and one year after the 2012 election. Standard errors clustered at the state level are in parentheses: 0.1; 0.05; and 0.01. Included control variables are log(population), % rural, % below poverty line, % Black, and % Hispanic. All variables are as of 2010 and interacted with Month FE. Regressions are weighted by the state population.
Our preferred estimate is the more conservative specification in column 3.17 The results imply that sales rates were 7.3% lower in Delay states during the first six months than in NoDelay states.18 Columns 4 to 7 show that delay laws did not significantly affect overall BGCs or other gun-related transactions like long gun sales.
B. Robustness Checks
In appendix section B.1, we demonstrate that no other factors related to the existence of delay laws systematically affected handgun sales during the demand shock and provide a host of additional robustness and sensitivity checks. These additional analyses suggest that the omission of Texas reduces the effect, as the state's regression weights are redistributed to a large number of states. If each state suffers from measurement error with some probability, spreading the weights will increase the overall impact of mismeasurement. Furthermore, population weighting is necessary to correctly capture countrywide effects as the effect arises predominantly in urban areas. Placebo regressions, different sample definitions, or removing single states from the sample, results in levels and/or without seasonal differencing, weighting by the adult population, controlling for the economic environment, and using alternative clustering techniques confirm the robustness of our findings.
C. Mechanisms
Having established different reactions in handgun sales between Delay and NoDelay states, we proceed by evaluating whether our findings could be driven by impulsive consumers. The first approach to characterize impulsive agents is the potential divergence between plans and actions. In other words, impulsive consumers may decide to buy a firearm under the influence of transient emotions but eventually do not buy since these emotions have already passed. This should not be observed for regular, nonimpulsive consumers if they make a perfectly rational purchase decision. However, a delay in receiving the gun makes the purchase also less attractive for nonimpulsive consumers since it reduces the item's net present value. If, however, the decision not to buy is driven predominantly by standard exponential discounting, we should observe that longer delays reduce purchases substantially more than shorter delays. Impulsive agents, however, would be deterred by any delay since they cannot get hold of the firearm while being in a particular emotional state. The second key characteristic of impulsiveness would thus be that even very short delays should have a notable impact on the likelihood to buy.20
We start by investigating the congruence between plans to buy firearms and actual sales. This analysis uses Google searches for the term “gun store,” which serves as a proxy for public interest in buying a gun and has been identified as a strong predictor for firearm purchasing intentions in previous research by Scott and Varian (2014). Columns 1 and 2 in table 2 repeat our preferred regression specifications using Google searches for “gun store” as the dependent variable. We do not detect large or significantly different changes in search results, which provides evidence that the different evolution of gun sales in the wake of the demand shock was not driven by different preferences for and intentions to buy firearms.21 This is also additional evidence that our results are unlikely to be driven by unobserved state heterogeneity. More important, these findings indicate a mismatch between firearm purchase intentions and actual sales in Delay states. However, these results could also reflect that potential buyers do not know their state's firearm laws while searching for a gun store but only learn about delays at a later point and then deliberately decide not to buy. For such nonimpulsive consumers, we should observe that decreasing delay lengths smoothly reduce the effect, which we test for next.
. | Log std'zed share of Google searches for “gun store” . | Log of handgun BGCs per 100,000 inhabitants . | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Maximum delay length . | . | . | Baseline (12 delay states) . | Drop NY (11) . | Drop MD, NC, NJ (8) . | Drop CA, DC MN, RI (4) . | ||||
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . | (9) . | (10) . |
Delay Post1 | 0.043 | −0.045 | −0.081* | −0.073** | −0.074 | −0.072** | −0.105** | −0.088** | −0.071** | −0.074* |
(0.072) | (0.080) | (0.045) | (0.033) | (0.049) | (0.035) | (0.052) | (0.041) | (0.035) | (0.038) | |
Delay Post2 | −0.029 | −0.116 | 0.008 | 0.005 | 0.012 | 0.001 | −0.001 | −0.004 | −0.131** | −0.173 |
(0.104) | (0.138) | (0.066) | (0.086) | (0.072) | (0.094) | (0.080) | (0.116) | (0.058) | (0.119) | |
Year-Month FE | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Controls | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y |
State Trends | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y |
States | 49 | 49 | 43 | 43 | 42 | 42 | 39 | 39 | 35 | 35 |
Observations | 1,764 | 1,764 | 1,516 | 1,516 | 1,480 | 1,480 | 1,374 | 1,374 | 1,230 | 1,230 |
0.276 | 0.310 | 0.538 | 0.591 | 0.547 | 0.599 | 0.558 | 0.603 | 0.612 | 0.661 | |
0.98 | 0.99 | 0.54 | 0.7 | 0.97 | 0.98 |
. | Log std'zed share of Google searches for “gun store” . | Log of handgun BGCs per 100,000 inhabitants . | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Maximum delay length . | . | . | Baseline (12 delay states) . | Drop NY (11) . | Drop MD, NC, NJ (8) . | Drop CA, DC MN, RI (4) . | ||||
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . | (9) . | (10) . |
Delay Post1 | 0.043 | −0.045 | −0.081* | −0.073** | −0.074 | −0.072** | −0.105** | −0.088** | −0.071** | −0.074* |
(0.072) | (0.080) | (0.045) | (0.033) | (0.049) | (0.035) | (0.052) | (0.041) | (0.035) | (0.038) | |
Delay Post2 | −0.029 | −0.116 | 0.008 | 0.005 | 0.012 | 0.001 | −0.001 | −0.004 | −0.131** | −0.173 |
(0.104) | (0.138) | (0.066) | (0.086) | (0.072) | (0.094) | (0.080) | (0.116) | (0.058) | (0.119) | |
Year-Month FE | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Controls | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y |
State Trends | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y |
States | 49 | 49 | 43 | 43 | 42 | 42 | 39 | 39 | 35 | 35 |
Observations | 1,764 | 1,764 | 1,516 | 1,516 | 1,480 | 1,480 | 1,374 | 1,374 | 1,230 | 1,230 |
0.276 | 0.310 | 0.538 | 0.591 | 0.547 | 0.599 | 0.558 | 0.603 | 0.612 | 0.661 | |
0.98 | 0.99 | 0.54 | 0.7 | 0.97 | 0.98 |
Specifications as per table 1. Google search results include % with Internet access as additional controls.
In columns 3 to 10 of table 2, we use our two main specifications from table 1 and gradually exclude states with delay lengths exceeding thirty, fourteen, and three days. The table also features tests for coefficient equality of in the short-delay and the baseline sample. Overall, we do not detect strong variations in the estimated coefficients for . In the most restrictive specifications 9 and 10, with only four treatment states and at most three days of delay, the estimates are still very close to the baseline in columns 3 and 4. The Wald tests can never confidently reject the null hypothesis of coefficient equality for . The absence of a systematic decrease in the effect size suggests that gun buyers may in fact respond more to the presence of a delay per se rather than its length.22 This evidence lends further support to the above conjecture that the difference in sales between the two groups of states is predominantly driven by impulsive consumers.
A competing explanation for the relative drop in handgun sales would be fear of tighter gun legislation. Such legislation would be particularly binding in NoDelay states, which generally exhibit weaker gun legislation. The results in this and the previous section offer some insights into why this may not be the case. First, the Google search results in table 2 favor impulsiveness as an explanation over rational, forward-looking behavior. Second, since firearm ownership is a constitutional right and handgun ownership, in particular, cannot easily be prohibited by the states, any belief in substantially more binding handgun ownership restrictions may be classified as distorted.23 Holding such distorted beliefs makes further nonrational behavior conceivable. Third, the robustness checks in appendix table 7 and appendix sections B.1 and B.2 show that gun law strictness (or its absence) by and large does not explain away the effect of delay laws.
VI. The Effect of Delay Laws on Homicides
A. Results
Having found that handgun sales increased significantly less in Delay states during the 2012 firearm demand shock, we investigate whether there was also a corresponding effect on homicide rates. Table 3 shows the results from equation (2). Observations are now at the county-month level, and the sample includes all states previously omitted due to measurement error in the NICS data. Column 1 shows that Delay states saw a significant relative drop in gun homicide rates by 2.4% after the start of the firearm demand shock and an insignificant 1.4% relative decrease during Post2. Controlling for observables in column 2 yields a significant 2.2% relative drop in Delay states' handgun homicide rates during the treatment period Post1 and an insignificant relative decline of 1.8% in Post2. The inclusion of county trends in column 3 mainly leads to a loss in precision but only slightly diminishes to , which is still significant at 5%.24
. | Log of per 100,000 inhabitants . | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Homicides . | All violent crimes . | |||||||
. | Handgun . | Any . | Other . | . | . | ||||
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . | (9) . |
Delay Post1 | −0.024*** | −0.022*** | −0.019** | −0.024** | −0.021 | −0.001 | −0.000 | 0.004 | 0.002 |
(0.009) | (0.008) | (0.010) | (0.012) | (0.015) | (0.010) | (0.013) | (0.019) | (0.023) | |
Delay Post2 | −0.014 | −0.018 | −0.016 | 0.003 | 0.005 | 0.023*** | 0.024** | −0.018 | −0.019 |
(0.012) | (0.015) | (0.018) | (0.017) | (0.022) | (0.008) | (0.011) | (0.028) | (0.033) | |
Year-Month FE | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Controls | N | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y |
County Trends | N | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y |
Counties | 3,047 | 3,047 | 3,047 | 3,047 | 3,047 | 3,047 | 3,047 | 2,091 | 2,091 |
Observations | 109,692 | 109,692 | 109,692 | 109,692 | 109,692 | 109,692 | 109,692 | 75,276 | 75,276 |
0.002 | 0.008 | 0.019 | 0.006 | 0.016 | 0.005 | 0.014 | 0.007 | 0.034 |
. | Log of per 100,000 inhabitants . | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Homicides . | All violent crimes . | |||||||
. | Handgun . | Any . | Other . | . | . | ||||
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . | (9) . |
Delay Post1 | −0.024*** | −0.022*** | −0.019** | −0.024** | −0.021 | −0.001 | −0.000 | 0.004 | 0.002 |
(0.009) | (0.008) | (0.010) | (0.012) | (0.015) | (0.010) | (0.013) | (0.019) | (0.023) | |
Delay Post2 | −0.014 | −0.018 | −0.016 | 0.003 | 0.005 | 0.023*** | 0.024** | −0.018 | −0.019 |
(0.012) | (0.015) | (0.018) | (0.017) | (0.022) | (0.008) | (0.011) | (0.028) | (0.033) | |
Year-Month FE | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Controls | N | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y |
County Trends | N | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y |
Counties | 3,047 | 3,047 | 3,047 | 3,047 | 3,047 | 3,047 | 3,047 | 2,091 | 2,091 |
Observations | 109,692 | 109,692 | 109,692 | 109,692 | 109,692 | 109,692 | 109,692 | 75,276 | 75,276 |
0.002 | 0.008 | 0.019 | 0.006 | 0.016 | 0.005 | 0.014 | 0.007 | 0.034 |
Observations are at the county-month level. The sample period is November 2010 to October 2013, an asymmetric 36-month window 2 years before and 1 year after the 2012 election. Standard errors clustered at the state level are in parentheses: 0.1; 0.05; and 0.01. Included control variables are log(population), % rural, % below poverty line, % Black and % Hispanic. All variables are as of 2010 and interacted with Month FE. Regressions are weighted by the county population.
Columns 4 and 5 show that the effect for handgun homicides is also reflected in decreased aggregate homicide rates of similar magnitude. This effect is significant at the 5% level without trends but loses significance when these are included. Notably, there is virtually no impact of delay laws on overall homicides in the period. The reason for this becomes apparent when looking at specifications 6 and 7, which show a significant increase during for nonhandgun homicides. A straightforward explanation could be that the reaction of NoDelay states reflects two different channels through which increased handgun ownership can affect homicides. One would be a lethality effect by which random acts of aggression or anger turn into the shooting and killing of another person. The second effect would be a substitution effect whereby homicides are simply carried out using handguns instead of other weapons with no aggregate effect. While the former suggests an immediate, impulsive killing that would not have arisen without a gun, the latter constitutes a less specific crime that would have taken place in any case. Our results are indicative of both effects, with lethality being more prevalent during Post1 and substitution dominating the Post2 period (possibly because homicides are generally more prevalent in the months of the year also included in Post2). Since our main interest is delay laws' aggregate effects, the remainder of the paper focuses on the lethality effect and the impact of delay laws on handgun-related homicides during the Post1 period.
Columns 8 and 9 use the violent crime rate (following the FBI's definition) as the dependent variable to investigate whether the decrease in homicides may have been counteracted by an increase in other types of violent crime and thus provide a test of the “more guns, less crime” hypothesis. The estimated coefficients, however, are insignificant, small in magnitude for the Post1 period, and point in the same direction as the coefficient for homicides. If anything, more handguns increased violent crime in our setting.25
B. Robustness Checks
We run similar checks as in section VB to establish the validity of our identification strategy. First, we investigate the possibility of nonlinear pretrends using the same event-study design as for the NICS data. Panel B of figure 4 indeed does not show any systematic effect for handgun-induced homicides before the onset of the treatment.26 During our treatment period Post1, however, there is a clear negative impact for the first quarter following the demand shock and a slightly smaller one for the second treatment quarter, which lines up with the patterns observed for handgun sales rates in panel A of figure 4.27 In appendix section B.2, we show that our findings on handgun homicide rates are also not a by-product of underlying differences in political leanings, law stringency, and preferences for and supply of firearms, and we discuss and report placebo checks, state-level results, and sensitivity to alternative sample definitions, data transformation, and weighting choices. As with the BGC results, population weighting is necessary to correctly capture countrywide effects as the effect arises predominantly in urban areas. Placebo regressions, different sample definitions, and removing individual states from the sample result in levels and/or without seasonal differencing, weighting by the adult population, controlling for the economic environment, applying other clustering techniques, and using state-level aggregates confirm the robustness of our findings.
C. Mechanisms
Section VC provided tentative evidence that impulsive consumers are likely to drive the differences in handgun sale BGCs between Delay and NoDelay states. In this section, we provide evidence that our results on homicides can also be traced back to impulsive behavior. We do so by taking a closer look at the type of additional handgun homicides in NoDelay states (or, equivalently, which were “prevented” in Delay states).
Panel A of table 4 presents the results split up by victim sex with a particular focus on the 20 to 29 age group, into which the majority of first-time buyers should fall.28 The results show that men make up about two-thirds of the victims while women account for one-third. The coefficients for female victims, however, are more precisely estimated. Both male and female victims are predominantly aged 20 to 29. These findings suggest that female victims are overrepresented, as less than 10% of overall homicide victims are women in our data.29 Given this and our evidence on impulsive consumers, we investigate the role of domestic violence. To do so, we split the handgun homicide victims into those who were shot in their homes and those who were assaulted elsewhere. Panel B of table 4 reports the corresponding results. For the male victims, we find that the entire effect is driven by attacks outside their homes. Female victims are predominantly assaulted in their place of living, consistent with instances of domestic violence.
. | A. Victim age . | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Log of handgun homicides per 100,000 inhabitants . | |||||||||
Victim sex . | Any . | Male . | Female . | |||||||
Victim age . | Any . | Any . | 20–29 . | Any . | 20–29 . | |||||
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . | (9) . | (10) . |
Delay Post1 | −0.022*** | −0.019** | −0.013 | −0.011 | −0.011* | −0.008 | −0.008** | −0.008* | −0.006*** | −0.006** |
(0.008) | (0.010) | (0.008) | (0.009) | (0.006) | (0.006) | (0.003) | (0.005) | (0.002) | (0.002) | |
Delay Post2 | −0.018 | −0.016 | −0.018 | −0.016 | 0.002 | 0.005 | 0.002 | 0.002 | −0.002 | −0.002 |
(0.015) | (0.018) | (0.013) | (0.015) | (0.007) | (0.008) | (0.005) | (0.007) | (0.002) | (0.003) | |
County Trends | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y |
Mean DV levels | 0.287 | 0.287 | 0.243 | 0.243 | 0.099 | 0.099 | 0.045 | 0.045 | 0.012 | 0.012 |
0.008 | 0.019 | 0.008 | 0.020 | 0.012 | 0.023 | 0.005 | 0.014 | 0.007 | 0.016 | |
B. Place of Assault | ||||||||||
Victim sex | Any | Male | Female | |||||||
Place of assault | Any | Home | Not Home | Home | Not Home | |||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) | |
Delay Post1 | −0.022*** | −0.019** | 0.006 | 0.004 | −0.018* | −0.014 | −0.007** | −0.008** | −0.001 | 0.000 |
(0.008) | (0.010) | (0.008) | (0.008) | (0.009) | (0.011) | (0.003) | (0.004) | (0.002) | (0.003) | |
Delay Post2 | −0.018 | −0.016 | −0.012* | −0.014* | −0.008 | −0.004 | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.000 | 0.002 |
(0.015) | (0.018) | (0.006) | (0.008) | (0.011) | (0.012) | (0.005) | (0.006) | (0.002) | (0.003) | |
County Trends | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y |
Mean DV levels | 0.287 | 0.287 | 0.083 | 0.083 | 0.159 | 0.159 | 0.027 | 0.027 | 0.018 | 0.018 |
0.008 | 0.019 | 0.006 | 0.017 | 0.011 | 0.022 | 0.004 | 0.014 | 0.006 | 0.016 | |
C. Circumstances | ||||||||||
Log of handgun murders per 100,000 inhabitants | ||||||||||
Circumstances | Any | Arguments | Brawls | Gang, Felony, or Defense | All Other | |||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) | |
Delay Post1 | −0.015 | −0.018 | −0.011*** | −0.018*** | 0.002 | 0.002 | −0.001 | −0.010 | −0.007 | 0.003 |
(0.011) | (0.013) | (0.004) | (0.006) | (0.001) | (0.001) | (0.009) | (0.010) | (0.012) | (0.010) | |
Delay Post2 | −0.008 | −0.011 | −0.009* | −0.015* | −0.000 | −0.000 | −0.011 | −0.019 | 0.013 | 0.023 |
(0.017) | (0.022) | (0.005) | (0.008) | (0.001) | (0.001) | (0.008) | (0.014) | (0.012) | (0.016) | |
County Trends | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y |
Mean DV levels | 0.253 | 0.253 | 0.049 | 0.049 | 0.003 | 0.003 | 0.080 | 0.080 | 0.121 | 0.121 |
0.011 | 0.022 | 0.009 | 0.021 | 0.013 | 0.024 | 0.022 | 0.043 | 0.010 | 0.026 |
. | A. Victim age . | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Log of handgun homicides per 100,000 inhabitants . | |||||||||
Victim sex . | Any . | Male . | Female . | |||||||
Victim age . | Any . | Any . | 20–29 . | Any . | 20–29 . | |||||
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . | (9) . | (10) . |
Delay Post1 | −0.022*** | −0.019** | −0.013 | −0.011 | −0.011* | −0.008 | −0.008** | −0.008* | −0.006*** | −0.006** |
(0.008) | (0.010) | (0.008) | (0.009) | (0.006) | (0.006) | (0.003) | (0.005) | (0.002) | (0.002) | |
Delay Post2 | −0.018 | −0.016 | −0.018 | −0.016 | 0.002 | 0.005 | 0.002 | 0.002 | −0.002 | −0.002 |
(0.015) | (0.018) | (0.013) | (0.015) | (0.007) | (0.008) | (0.005) | (0.007) | (0.002) | (0.003) | |
County Trends | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y |
Mean DV levels | 0.287 | 0.287 | 0.243 | 0.243 | 0.099 | 0.099 | 0.045 | 0.045 | 0.012 | 0.012 |
0.008 | 0.019 | 0.008 | 0.020 | 0.012 | 0.023 | 0.005 | 0.014 | 0.007 | 0.016 | |
B. Place of Assault | ||||||||||
Victim sex | Any | Male | Female | |||||||
Place of assault | Any | Home | Not Home | Home | Not Home | |||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) | |
Delay Post1 | −0.022*** | −0.019** | 0.006 | 0.004 | −0.018* | −0.014 | −0.007** | −0.008** | −0.001 | 0.000 |
(0.008) | (0.010) | (0.008) | (0.008) | (0.009) | (0.011) | (0.003) | (0.004) | (0.002) | (0.003) | |
Delay Post2 | −0.018 | −0.016 | −0.012* | −0.014* | −0.008 | −0.004 | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.000 | 0.002 |
(0.015) | (0.018) | (0.006) | (0.008) | (0.011) | (0.012) | (0.005) | (0.006) | (0.002) | (0.003) | |
County Trends | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y |
Mean DV levels | 0.287 | 0.287 | 0.083 | 0.083 | 0.159 | 0.159 | 0.027 | 0.027 | 0.018 | 0.018 |
0.008 | 0.019 | 0.006 | 0.017 | 0.011 | 0.022 | 0.004 | 0.014 | 0.006 | 0.016 | |
C. Circumstances | ||||||||||
Log of handgun murders per 100,000 inhabitants | ||||||||||
Circumstances | Any | Arguments | Brawls | Gang, Felony, or Defense | All Other | |||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) | |
Delay Post1 | −0.015 | −0.018 | −0.011*** | −0.018*** | 0.002 | 0.002 | −0.001 | −0.010 | −0.007 | 0.003 |
(0.011) | (0.013) | (0.004) | (0.006) | (0.001) | (0.001) | (0.009) | (0.010) | (0.012) | (0.010) | |
Delay Post2 | −0.008 | −0.011 | −0.009* | −0.015* | −0.000 | −0.000 | −0.011 | −0.019 | 0.013 | 0.023 |
(0.017) | (0.022) | (0.005) | (0.008) | (0.001) | (0.001) | (0.008) | (0.014) | (0.012) | (0.016) | |
County Trends | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y |
Mean DV levels | 0.253 | 0.253 | 0.049 | 0.049 | 0.003 | 0.003 | 0.080 | 0.080 | 0.121 | 0.121 |
0.011 | 0.022 | 0.009 | 0.021 | 0.013 | 0.024 | 0.022 | 0.043 | 0.010 | 0.026 |
Panels A and B: All regressions use 109,692 observations from 3,047 counties. Panel C: All regressions use 75,276 observations from 2,091 counties. Specifications as per table 3.
To further investigate the role of domestic violence and impulsive killings more generally, we present results using the UCR SHR data on homicide circumstances in panel C of table 4.30 Columns 1 and 2 show the baseline specification for handgun homicides reported in the UCR SHR and then split these into specific murder circumstances. The results for aggregate handgun homicides have the same sign as those using the NVSS data but are only about two-thirds in size and insignificant, likely due to the more limited coverage and data quality. The results in columns 3 and 4, however, indicate that deadly assaults related to arguments account for the main part of the additional handgun homicides in NoDelay states. Unlike the aggregate handgun murder rate, this effect is also highly significant. All other types of homicide circumstances such as brawls, (organized) crime, and defense, as well as other/undetermined, do not seem to be systematically affected during the Post1 period. These findings lend further support to the hypothesis that impulsive consumers are driving the differences in handgun homicides during the demand shock.
Summarizing these findings, we observe that the additional homicides of women in NoDelay states primarily happened inside their home, predominantly to women between ages 20 and 29, and often as a result of arguments. Homicides of men happened primarily outside their home, but also primarily because of arguments. Male victims are also typically 20 to 29 years old. In terms of mechanisms, our findings suggest domestic violence and other heat-of-the-moment murders as a possible explanation for the observed differences in homicides between Delay and NoDelay states. These interpretations are in line with insights by Tangney, Baumeister, and Boone (2004) that impulsiveness is correlated across domains.
VII. Conclusion
In light of the persistently high rate of firearm homicides in the United States, understanding the consequences of legislation limiting access to guns is imperative. One of the main arguments that proponents of gun rights use is that gun laws do not substantially affect violent crime but impose excessive burdens on law-abiding gun owners. In this study, we focus on the effects of a specific type of policy measure, handgun purchase delay laws, and provide evidence that, while not infringing with Second Amendment rights, these laws can substantially reduce homicides by preventing impulsive purchases.
We present empirical evidence that states with delay laws in place saw comparatively lower handgun sales during a demand shock after the reelection of President Obama in 2012 and the shooting at Sandy Hook Elementary School. Further results show that purchase delays have strong effects even when they are very short and did not affect intentions to buy a firearm, only the likelihood of consumers making an actual handgun purchase. In the second part of our analysis, we investigate delay laws' effect on homicide rates. Using detailed micro data on mortality, we find a significant effect of delay laws on handgun-related homicides during the period of the demand shock. The effect size is about 2%, which in turn implies that about 200 homicides could have been prevented during the six-month Post1 period if all U.S. states had had some sort of purchase delay law in place. These additional homicides encompass both genders and indicate that arguments, as well as domestic violence, constitute some of the main channels through which handgun ownership by impulsive individuals may affect homicide rates.
We see our study as a good starting point for more nuanced investigations into the relationship between gun ownership and crime. First, additional direct evidence on the circumstances linking gun sales to violent crime is needed. While our results were able to point in the direction of arguments and domestic violence, the results are far from clear-cut. With increasing coverage of the FBI's National Incident-Based Reporting System (NIBRS), more detailed information on particular crime incidents could be used to study similar future firearm demand shocks. Second, given the absence of accurate data on how county-level gun ownership evolves, our study cannot pin down an exact gun-homicide elasticity. The NICS data are very noisy and make cross-state comparison impossible at times. We thus stress the need for a more transparent, county-level version of handgun sales than what is currently available. Finally, we believe that more research is needed to evaluate the costs and benefits of specific gun laws. As shown in this study, the positive effects of purchase delays may be understated. Rigorous analyses of gun laws may therefore help foster a more informed debate on gun policy.
Notes
All statements regarding a relative increase in handgun sales and homicides in states without handgun purchase delays are just the flip side of the relative decrease in handgun sales and homicides in states with such delays.
The identification strategy of overlaying cross-sectional variation in preexisting characteristics with a common time-series shock has also been applied in other work (see Nunn & Qian, 2011).
While gun-related accidents are not at the heart of our paper, supplementary results reported in the appendix based on our own identification strategy cannot replicate those findings. Our main results suggest that the primary detrimental effect of increased gun ownership after the Sandy Hook shooting was an increase in gun-related homicides.
Fees can range from $1 plus notary fee in Michigan to $340 in New York City ($100 in the state of New York). See https://www.cga.ct.gov/2013/rpt/2013-R-0048.htm.
Wisconsin repealed its 48-hour handgun waiting period in only 2015 and is thus part of our sample.
For purchasing permits, appendix table 27 states the maximum delay allowed by law. There is no reliable information on average delays that we are aware of. Because we binarize the treatment, averaging would be inconsequential for our analysis.
For convenience, we refer to the IHS transformation as log throughout the paper. We provide robustness checks in levels for our main specifications in the appendix.
In appendix section B.5, we show that neither the supply of nor the demand for gun shows (the latter measured by Google Search results) witnessed a more substantial impact of the demand shock in NoDelay over Delay states, effectively showing that displacement to these states does not seem to be a cause for concern.
This procedure could not be applied for Hawaii, Illinois, and Massachusetts as permit checks in these states may also include permits for long guns. Permits were also not added to handgun sale checks for Florida where, for no apparent reason, almost all months report no permit checks (and single digits for the other months) until April 2013, when they suddenly jump to 15,000 to 30,000 per month for the remainder of the sample period. Any further reference to handgun BGCs implicitly includes BGCs made for permits unless otherwise stated.
Outliers are mainly due to permit rechecks and law changes associated with large mechanic jumps in BGC activity. We provide explicit reasoning for these choices in appendix section A.2.
Our measure of handgun-related incidents also encompasses instances when an undetermined type of firearm was used. This should not bias our estimates in any way, and it is corroborated by the fact that the vast majority of homicides are carried out with handguns.
Further details on this procedure are reported in appendix section A.5.
Summary statistics of all variables can be found in appendix table 30. Appendix table 31 performs mean difference tests on the primary outcome and control variables.
Appendix figures 23/24 and 25/26 depict the evolution of both variables in levels and twelve-month growth rates.
Note that after applying seasonal differencing, the nominal sample period starts in November 2010 and covers 24 months before and 12 months after treatment onset.
Both specifications are informative, however, in our view. As we do not know whether the “true” model exhibits trends, it is ex ante unclear whether column 2 or 3 should be preferred. We therefore report specifications with and without trends for all results in order to provide a more complete picture.
Note that for all results in logs (IHS), the interpretation of the coefficients is a change in percentages. In levels, the coefficients represent percentage point changes.
For this analysis, we aggregate the data into three-month bins starting in November since “classic” quarters would result in one fully and two partially treated time periods. Appendix figure 31 shows the same graph using monthly data. Appendix figure 27 reports a similar event study graph without seasonal differencing extending over a longer period.
These predictions can also be formally derived in a theoretical framework, which is available on request but omitted here for the sake of space.
Figure 28 in the appendix shows the development of Google searches between November 2009 and October 2013 graphically. A regression using levels and producing similar results can be found in appendix table 28.
These findings are corroborated by a triple-difference analysis presented in appendix table 35. In appendix table 29, we also show that including transaction costs from, for example, gun licensing fees in our regressions does not qualitatively change our findings regarding the effect of purchase delay laws.
This follows from the landmark ruling of D.C. v. Heller, 554 U.S. 570 (2008).
Appendix section B.3 decomposes the overall violent crime rate and shows that aggregation does not hide substantial effects on individual categories of violent crime. Appendix section B.4 shows the effect on suicides and accidents.
Appendix figure 32 reports a similar event study graph using monthly data. Appendix figure 29 reports a similar event study graph without seasonal differencing extending over a more extended period.
Appendix figure 30 shows no systematic effect on non-handgun homicides before or during our treatment. The positive effect during Post2 in the baseline regressions applies to all three-month periods but is statistically significant only for May to July 2013.
Appendix table 32 shows corresponding results for all other age groups. We also report victim splits by race in appendix table 33 and show that in line with the overall demographics of homicide victims in the United States, victims tend to be almost evenly categorized as White or Black.
To judge how common homicides of each category are, panels A, B, and C of table 4, as well as appendix tables 32 and 33, include an additional row reporting the mean of the nondifferenced dependent variable in levels.
As outlined in section IIIB, these data exhibit a more restricted coverage. Appendix table 34 shows that the UCR SHR data yield qualitatively similar estimates compared to the NVSS data in our Post1 period of interest. A map illustrating the exact coverage for the UCR data is shown in appendix figure 12.
REFERENCES
Author notes
This paper supersedes a previous version, entitled “Dynamics in Gun Ownership and Crime—Evidence from the Aftermath of Sandy Hook.” We thank participants of numerous seminars and conferences for feedback. The paper benefited from helpful comments by Bocar Ba, Sascha O. Becker, Aaron Chalfin, Amanda Chuan, Florian Englmaier, Stephan Heblich, Alessandro Iaria, Judd Kessler, Martin Kocher, Botond Kőszegi, Florentin Krämer, Katherine Milkman, Takeshi Murooka, Emily Owens, Arnaud Philippe, Alex Rees-Jones, Marco Schwarz, Simeon Schudy, Peter Schwardmann, Hans H. Sievertsen, Lisa Spantig, Uwe Sunde, Ben Vollaard, Fabian Waldinger, Mark Westcott, Julia Wirtz, Daniel Wissmann, Noam Yuchtman, and, in particular, Yanos Zylberberg. The comments of Shachar Kariv and three referees substantially improved an earlier draft. D.S. thanks the Department of Business Economics and Public Policy at the Wharton School, where parts of this paper were written, for its hospitality.
A supplemental appendix is available online at https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_01106.