During the early 1990s, Germany offered temporary protection to 700,000 Yugoslavian refugees fleeing war. By 2000, many had been repatriated. We exploit this natural experiment to investigate the role of returning migrants in boosting export performance upon their return. Using confidential German administrative data, we find that industries with 10% more returning refugees exhibit larger exports between the pre- and postwar periods by 1% to 1.6%. We use exogenous allocation rules for asylum seekers within Germany as an instrument to deal with endogeneity concerns. We show evidence pointing to productivity shifts as the main mechanism behind our results. Consistently, we find our results are driven by refugees in occupations more likely to transfer knowledge, technologies, and best practices.

AS of today, there are over 26 million refugees hosted in a foreign country. This figure is likely to keep increasing as sources of displacement such as ongoing conflict and climate change pose important challenges to stability around the globe. For the most part, refugees in host countries face hurdles to integrate due to negative perceptions of their effect on local labor markets, crime levels, or social cohesion. Despite the negative public sentiment, refugees, and migrants alike, represent important economic opportunities for both their host communities and home countries, as evidenced by a small but growing literature.1 Yet to the best of our knowledge, there is no rigorous study documenting the crucial role refugees can play in shaping large-scale economic outcomes (such as a country’s industrial or export structure) in their home countries upon return. This paper fills this gap by documenting the long-run effect of returning migrants on industry-level exports driven by productivity shifts, using the case of Yugoslavian refugees during the 1990s.

We exploit a natural experiment and document a systematic relationship between refugees spending time and gaining work experience in a foreign country and the subsequent export performance at home of the same sectors in which they had worked while abroad upon their return. The context is the early 1990s, when about 700,000 citizens of what was then Yugoslavia fled to Germany escaping war. Most Yugoslavian migrants in the first half of the 1990s were given a Duldung status (German for “toleration”), in effect a temporary protection status, or more specifically, a “suspended deportation” permit. After the Dayton peace agreement was signed in 1995, the protection status of temporary migrants was revoked, forcing them to leave the country. By 2000, the majority of these migrants had been repatriated back to their home country or to other territories of the dissolved Yugoslavia.

Using confidential administrative data from the Institute for Employment Research (IAB), we identify returning migrants as Yugoslavian workers who entered the German labor force (by industry) between 1991 and 1995 and had left it by the year 2000. In this sense, our “treatment” reflects the extent to which Yugoslavian refugees were exposed to German productive knowledge. We link this information to standard industry-level international trade data and employ a difference-in-differences methodology to estimate changes in export values from the former Yugoslavia to the rest of the world. The different data sources we rely on limit us from linking both exports and migrants to the different nations that emerged after the dissolution of Yugoslavia. We overcome this limitation, however, by aggregating data for all former Yugoslavian nations in order to construct an industry-level panel data. We find that the industries that perform better in terms of exports in the years following the repatriation are the very same ones in which refugees worked while in Germany.

In order to address concerns of endogeneity due to, for example, self-selection of workers into certain industries, we instrument for the actual number of returning workers per industry using a spatial dispersal policy that exogenously allocated asylum seekers across the different administrative regions of Germany upon arrival.

Our main finding is that industries with a 1% increase in return migration (as defined by our treatment) experienced an increase in exports to the rest of the world of 0.1% to 0.16% between the pre- and postwar periods. Based on all the returning refugees in our sample, this represents up to 6% of all the export growth of former Yugoslavian nations between 1990 and 2005, most of it occurring after 2000.

Our results are robust to an estimation in the form of an event-study, which shows that there are no existing previous trends for industries treated at different levels of intensity and that the treatment effect becomes larger with time. In addition, we complement our main difference-in-difference results by applying the synthetic control method (Abadie & Gardeazabal, 2003; Abadie et al., 2010, 2015) to create a counterfactual for every Yugoslavian export industry in our sample. We find that real Yugoslavian industries outperform their synthetic counterparts, on average, with this pattern being particularly strong for industries associated with more intense treatment.

When exploring mechanisms driving our main findings, we find robust evidence that points to industry-specific productivity shifts brought on by returning refugees as the main driving force of export performance. In particular, our findings are robust to substituting actual exports with a constructed measure of revealed comparative advantage based on Costinot et al. (2012), which arguably reflects productivity dynamics, and we replicate our analysis using more aggregated data to study changes in labor productivity (as measured by output per worker, added value per worker, and wages) using data from the UN Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO), as well as using sectoral data on exports per worker and size (firms and workers) for the specific case of Bosnia. We find that all these complementary results are consistent with our main findings.

Through numerous empirical tests, we also rule out a number of alternative explanations, which include our results being driven by purely scale effects or convergence patterns in structural transformation. We also rule out channels that the literature links to migration flows and could also explain export performance, such as capital formation and reduction of international trade transaction costs due to migrant networks. While exploring these channels provides us with additional insights, we find no evidence in them to invalidate the results that point to productivity shifts as a mechanism driving our results.

Consistently with productivity shifts, we then document that our results are particularly driven by certain types of workers and occupations, which would be more likely to transfer knowledge, technologies, and best practices across borders, and thus able to induce productivity improvements. For instance, our results are driven by workers with high educational attainment, in occupations intensive in analytical tasks (as opposed to manual ones), occupations that can be classified as professional and/or skill intensive, and occupations that have managerial characteristics. We also find that our results are stronger when looking at workers who, while abroad, experienced faster wage growth and were employed by the top-paying firms within each industry.

Our findings contribute to the economic literature at large by documenting substantial industry-specific productivity increases, resulting in changes in the export industrial composition of a country as a whole, as a result of returning migrants who were exposed to foreign knowledge, technologies, and best practices. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first paper documenting such large-scale and country-level industrial productivity shifts induced by return migration in the context of a natural experiment.2

Our paper contributes to a number of strands of the literature. First, we contribute to the literature on migrants as drivers of international knowledge diffusion back to their home countries (Kerr, 2008; Agrawal et al., 2006, 2011; Breschi et al., 2017; Bahar & Rapoport, 2018; Miguélez, 2018; Miguelez & Noumedem Temgoua, 2020; Bahar et al., 2019) and, relatedly, to a burgeoning literature that looks at migrants as drivers of productivity shifts (Scoville, 1952a, 1952b; Markusen & Trofimenko, 2009; Poole, 2013; Choudhury, 2016; Hornung, 2014; Malchow-Møller et al., 2017; Bryan & Morten, 2019). Second, our results speak to the important link between migration and economic development, given the substantial role of migrants affecting structural transformation, an important driver of economic growth (Imbs & Wacziarg, 2003; Hausmann et al., 2006; Hidalgo et al., 2007; Koren & Tenreyro, 2007; Cadot et al., 2011). Third, we contribute to the growing literature emphasizing the role of managerial skills as a crucial determinant of productivity (Bloom & Van Reenen, 2007; Bloom et al., 2013; Giorcelli, 2019) and of exports (Bloom et al., 2021). Finally, we contribute to a growing number of studies that focus on consequences of forced displacement for the refugees’ home countries (Waldinger, 2010, 2012; Acemoglu et al., 2011; Grosfeld et al., 2013; Akbulut-Yuksel & Yuksel, 2015; Bharadwaj et al., 2015; Pascali, 2016; Huber et al., 2021; Testa, 2020; Mayda et al., 2022), as well as to the literature of the economic consequences of return migration (McCormick & Wahba, 2001; Dustmann & Kirchkamp, 2002; Mesnard, 2004; Wahba & Zenou, 2012; Batista et al., 2017).3

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II provides a description of the historical context of the Yugoslavian refugee crisis. Section III details the data sources and the empirical strategy. Section IV presents the main results and performs a series of robustness tests. Section V explores possible mechanisms driving our results, and section VI exploits heterogeneity effects based on the characteristics and occupations of the refugees. Section VII concludes. The paper is accompanied by an online appendix, which we refer to throughout the text.

A. The Refugee Crisis and Integration in Germany

In June 1991, the Socialist Federal Republic of Yugoslavia started to disintegrate following several armed conflicts and ethnic civil wars. Fighting began with the “Ten-Day War” in summer 1991 after Slovenia declared its independence. Soon after, the conflict spread to Croatia and later, in 1992, to Bosnia and Herzegovina. It was only in December 1995, with the signing of the Dayton Peace Accord involving President Clinton, that the armed conflict officially ended.

During the armed conflict, around 3.7 million people (roughly 16% of the Yugoslavian population) were displaced and fled from their homes, making this episode the largest migration flow in Europe since the end of World War II (Radovic, 2005). While many affected by the war became internally displaced, about 800,000 people resettled outside the boundaries of the former Yugoslavia, hoping to find refuge in other countries (Lederer, 1997).4 Among these countries, Germany was one of the best suited to receive these refugees because of the already significant Yugoslavian community residing there and Germany’s ability and willingness to provide protection to those fleeing the war.5 The flow of refugees into Germany responded to the dynamics of the conflict: in the early stages of the war, involving mostly Croatians, about 100,000 of them arrived in Germany; later, when the war spread to Bosnia, acts of systematic violence triggered massive outflows from those areas, and Germany hosted some 350,000 Bosnian refugees. Simultaneously, Germany also received another 250,000 Yugoslavians mainly from Serbia and Kosovo. Thus, overall during the first half of the 1990s, Germany received roughly 700,000 migrants from Yugoslavia, making it by far the largest recipient foreign country (see Lederer, 1997, for a detailed account of these flows).

Most of Yugoslavian refugees who arrived in Germany were given a temporary protection status, known as Duldung, which can be translated to English as “toleration.”6 The temporary character of the Duldung status constituted a “suspended deportation” status. In other words, Duldung holders were allowed to remain in Germany until the permit expired, after which they were obliged to leave the country immediately. While the Duldung duration upon issuance was set to six months, the authorities had the option to renew it. De facto, the Duldung status was renewed for all holders as long as the war continued.

A less popular option for Yugoslavians fleeing the war and arriving in Germany was to apply for asylum. According to Article 16(a) of the German Basic Law (Grundgesetz), an individual is eligible to seek asylum if he or she faces individual persecution and is able to prove so. If granted asylum, the individual enters a path toward permanent residency (Hailbronner, 2003). Asylum recognition rates, however, were very low for citizens from the former Yugoslavia (Lederer, 1997, documents that between 1992 and 1995, only 1% of Bosnian applicants were granted asylum). This is because most of them could not prove to the German authorities they were facing individual persecution at home following the standards set by the German authorities at the time (Dimova, 2006). Importantly enough, however, asylum seekers whose request was denied also were able to receive Duldung status, since the German authorities were not deporting these refugees back into active war zones.

A large number of Yugoslavian refugees integrated into the German labor force after their arrival. For instance, in 1992 alone, the number of workers from (former) Yugoslavia rose by 15.3% to 375,000 (Deutscher-Bundestag, 1994). Overall, both Duldung holders and asylum seekers had relatively good access to the labor market.7 But there was an important difference between the two statuses concerned with respect to their mobility. Duldung holders faced no geographical limitation. But asylum seekers were subjected to mandatory residency (Residenzpflicht) within the region in which their application was initiated while it was processed.8 The decision on which region would process the application was made by the authorities based on preestablished quotas. This limitation on geographic mobility for asylum seekers is an important part of our identification strategy, which we detail in section IIID.

Generally refugees found employment across diverse sectors and relied on different channels to secure their jobs. Some were able to use their network of friends and family relatives, some relied on local employment agencies, and some found work by themselves (Walker, 2010; Ruben et al., 2009).

B. End of the War and Deportation

The signature of the Dayton Peace Accord in December 1995 officially marked the end of the war that started in 1991. After that date, the German authorities had no reason to renew the Duldung status of refugees and indeed enacted the imminent deportation of refugees back to the former Yugoslavia.9 In fact, only one day after the signing of the Dayton Accord, Germany formally announced a repatriation plan through which Duldung refugees were gradually forced to leave the country (Dimova, 2006), often simultaneously rolling out assisted repatriation programs (Bosswick, 2000).10

Repatriation was planned in two main phases. The first phase targeted single adults and childless couples, as well as people with family back in their home country. The second phase targeted the rest of the refugees. By summer 1996, letters requesting deportation were sent out, and by the end of 1996, deportations had begun. Repatriation and deportations continued until 2000, though most of them had happened by 1998. Figures by international organizations and independent academic research suggest that about 75% of Yugoslavian civil war refugees returned to their home country or to another former Yugoslavian nation, with an additional 15% settling in third countries and only about 10% remaining in Germany (UNHCR, 2005; Ruhl & Lederer, 2001; Lederer, 1997).11 With respect to Croatian refugees, Lederer (1997, 310) explains: “During the Croatian-Serbian War (1991 to 1993) numerous Croatians were also admitted to the Federal Republic of Germany. According to information from the Federal Ministry of the Interior of 9 October 1996, most of the original 100,000 Croatian refugees should have returned to their homeland within the framework of the repatriation process that began in 1994. However, the Federal Ministry of the Interior notes that there is no precise information on this from the federal states.”

Figure 1a plots the evolution of the population size of Yugoslavia (as a whole) over time during the period of our study. It shows, consistent with the historic accounts, overall population drops significantly after 1991, and following the end of the war (1995) it grows again. In 2005 the population of the former Yugoslavian countries combined was comparable to the population of Yugoslavia before the war, in 1990.

Population in Yugoslavia and Migration to Germany

Figure 1.
Population in Yugoslavia and Migration to Germany

Panel a plots the population of the (former) Yugoslavia over time, sourced from the Maddison Project Database 2018. Panel b shows the net inflow, stock, and asylum requests of migrants from the (former) Yugoslavia into Germany from 1980 until 2010. The number of migrant stocks by nationality is based on the Central Register of Foreigners (Ausländerzentralregister). The data have been downloaded from the online database of the German Federal Statistical Office (Statistisches Bundesamt). Data on migration flows and asylum applications by nationality are from the German Federal Statistical Office and the Federal Office for Migration and Refugees (Bundesamt für Migration und Flüchtlinge), respectively, and sent to us upon request.

Figure 1.
Population in Yugoslavia and Migration to Germany

Panel a plots the population of the (former) Yugoslavia over time, sourced from the Maddison Project Database 2018. Panel b shows the net inflow, stock, and asylum requests of migrants from the (former) Yugoslavia into Germany from 1980 until 2010. The number of migrant stocks by nationality is based on the Central Register of Foreigners (Ausländerzentralregister). The data have been downloaded from the online database of the German Federal Statistical Office (Statistisches Bundesamt). Data on migration flows and asylum applications by nationality are from the German Federal Statistical Office and the Federal Office for Migration and Refugees (Bundesamt für Migration und Flüchtlinge), respectively, and sent to us upon request.

Close modal

Figure 1b plots the “mirror image”: the inflow of around 700,000 refugees from the former Yugoslavia who arrived in Germany in the first half of the 1990s. In 1980, there were already about 600,000 Yugoslavians residing in Germany. This stock remained steady until the late 1980s when the net inflow of Yugoslavian migrants started to grow at a rate of 25,000 per year, including until the year 1990. This rate skyrocketed to 168,000, 250,000, and 165,000 during 1991, 1992, and 1993, respectively. The sharp increase in the net inflow of migrants was fueled by refugees escaping war. We also see a sharp increase in asylum requests from Yugoslavian citizens during the same years.

Consistent with the accounts, the number of Yugoslavians in Germany sharply declines starting in 1996, after the Dayton treaty was signed. By 2000, close to 350,000 Yugoslavians had left the country. While some of them left to a third country, it has been estimated that the majority of them returned to countries of the (by then) former Yugoslavia (UNHCR, 2005; Ruhl & Lederer, 2001; Lederer, 1997), consistent with figure 1a.

In the German labor force, we see patterns consistent with the historical narrative described so far: both the inflow of Yugoslavian workers into the tradable sector labor force between the years 1991 and 1995 and their outflow in the years that followed are highly unusual as compared to foreign workers from other nationalities, as figure 2 shows. The figure plots the yearly share of Yugoslavian workers entering and exiting the labor force of Germany’s tradable sector. The share is always computed using the total number of all foreign workers entering and exiting the labor force in those same years at the denominator. It becomes clear from figure 2 that Yugoslavians entered the labor force in much higher proportions during the first half of the 1990s compared to the same proportion in years before 1990 and after 2000. We also see that Yugoslavian workers exited the German labor force in higher proportion during the latter half of the 1990s, consistent with the historical events.

Yugoslavian Workers’ Yearly Entry to and Exit from

Figure 2.
Yugoslavian Workers’ Yearly Entry to and Exit from

The graph shows the yearly share (out of all foreign workers) of Yugoslavians entering and exiting the labor force of Germany’s tradable sector.

Figure 2.
Yugoslavian Workers’ Yearly Entry to and Exit from

The graph shows the yearly share (out of all foreign workers) of Yugoslavians entering and exiting the labor force of Germany’s tradable sector.

Close modal

A. Data Sources

We link a number of data sets together for our study. First, we use data on exports for the period 1984 to 2014, which comes from bilateral trade data compiled by Feenstra et al. (2005), with extensions and corrections suggested by Hausmann et al. (2014; the original source of the trade data is UN Comtrade). In most cases our dependent variable is exports by industry from Yugoslavia to the rest of the world, excluding to Germany. We exclude Germany as a first attempt to reduce the possibility that our results are driven by lower transaction costs caused by migrant networks between the former Yugoslavian countries and Germany (Rauch & Trindade, 2002; Parsons & Vézina, 2018).12

Industries are defined using the four-digit Standard Industry Trade Classification (SITC) revision 2 and list 786 different varieties. This industry classification provides a disaggregation level that enables a meaningful discussion about export diversification patterns. Some examples of industries in this level of disaggregation are, for example, “Knitted/Crocheted Fabrics Elastic or Rubberized” (SITC 6553) and “Electrical Measuring, Checking, Analyzing Instruments” (SITC 8748). Following Hausmann et al. (2014), we exclude countries below 1 million citizens and total trade below USD $1 billion in 2010. Other variables created using trade data are explained as they are introduced into the analysis.

The data on migrant workers in Germany are based on records from the German social security system and comprise all persons employed subject to social security contributions, with the exception of self-employed and civil servants.13 The records indicate the industry where the workers are employed. Our sample is restricted to 40% random draws of foreign nationals observed on June 30 of each year from 1975 to 2014, augmented by the employment history of each individual for our sampling period. This amounts to about 2.4 million workers per year on average, a large enough number for the random draws to form a representative sample.14 Moreover, since we can observe the full employment history, we can determine whether an individual was employed before or after any given year in Germany, which we exploit to construct our treatment. Beyond individual information such as age, nationality, and educational attainment, the data include detailed occupational codes categorized in more than 300 different occupations (see more details on this data set in online appendix section B).

In order to construct an instrument to deal with endogeneity issues, we use inflow quotas mandated by the government that define the regional distribution of asylum seekers (Königsteiner Schlüssel). These quotas are determined yearly by the Joint Science Conference (Gemeinsame Wissenschaftskonferenz, GWK). The GWK sent to us, in response to our request, yearly data between 1990 and 2016.

With these data sets we are able to match the exports of Yugoslavia to the rest of the world with the number of Yugoslavian workers in Germany working in the same industry category.15

B. Main Outcome and Treatment Variables

Our main unit of analysis, which we use as our dependent variable in our baseline specification, is the combined exports by industry of Yugoslavia to the rest of the world, excluding to Germany (to avoid results being driven by lower transactions costs, as explained above). To construct this variable we combine per industry exports of Yugoslavia as a nation until 1991, with exports by industry of all countries combined that formed Yugoslavia after 1992: Bosnia and Herzegovina, Croatia, FYR of Macedonia, Montenegro, Serbia, and Slovenia (excluding trade within these countries).16 We focus on all former Yugoslavian countries as one following the disintegration because the German data used to construct our treatment do not allow us to distinguish which is the region of origin of the refugees within Yugoslavia (e.g., we only see that they entered the labor force with a Yugoslavian passport).

The main independent variable, the treatment, is the number of Yugoslavian refugees by (tradable) sector who (i) joined the German labor force between 1991 and 1995,17 (ii) had not been recorded in our data in 1990 or before, and (iii) had not been recorded in our data in 2000 or after.18 Applying this filter allows us to proxy for returning refugees with a high degree of certainty, consistent with the historical accounts described above.19

As already explained, a limitation of our data is that we cannot distinguish with full certainty whether these workers with Yugoslavian passports who left the labor force indeed returned to the former Yugoslavia. Thus, in our calculation of return migration, we are including workers who, for instance, stayed in Germany working in the informal sector or went to a third country. Yet all of these possibilities work against us in our estimation, implying that our estimates are to some extent understating the true effect of return migration. However, plenty of historic evidence suggests that indeed those who were repatriated went back and worked in related industries. For instance, Ruben et al. (2009) note that those who worked during their time in Germany were more likely to be employed when they returned to the former Yugoslavia, with many finding jobs in industries in which they had worked before the war. There is anecdotal evidence, too, suggesting that after returning to their home countries, refugees subsequently worked (or founded companies) in the same sector they had worked at in Germany (or other countries such as Sweden or Austria). In online appendix section A, we summarize some of the evidence we’ve collected on this. As these stories show, refugees benefited from their experiences in Germany in many ways, such as applying the acquired knowledge and skills about different production methods.

Figure 3 describes the treatment variable. It plots the number of Yugoslavian workers who entered the German workforce between 1991 and 1995 (horizontal axis) and the number of those workers who remain in the labor force beyond year 2000 (vertical axis), by four-digit SITC code. All observations are below the 45 degree line, simply because the number of migrants who stay in each industry beyond the year 2000 is a subset of all those who arrived between 1991 and 1995. Thus, the treatment is the difference between each one of the observations and the 45 degree line. As can be seen in the graph, there is variation in the treatment across industries. Some of the codes that stand out as having a large number of worker returnees are 8,219 (furniture parts), 6,911 (iron and steel structures), 5,989 (chemical products), and 2,482 (worked wood of coniferous). Based on our sample (which is limited to wage earners in the tradable sector), it is noticeable that “rate of return” as measured through our filter is substantial (about 30%), but not as high as what the historical acccounts suggest as documented in official reports from international organizations (e.g., UNHCR, 2005).20 The fact that some Yugoslavians stayed beyond 2000 for whatever reason is not a threat to our identification strategy, as long as these cases were not more or less frequent in some industries than in others. We expand on this in section IIID.

Yugoslavians in the German Workforce, by Industry

Figure 3.
Yugoslavians in the German Workforce, by Industry

The figure shows the number of Yugoslavian workers in the German workforce who arrived between 1991 and 1995 against those who remain in year 2000 and beyond. Marker labels indicate four-digit industries.

Figure 3.
Yugoslavians in the German Workforce, by Industry

The figure shows the number of Yugoslavian workers in the German workforce who arrived between 1991 and 1995 against those who remain in year 2000 and beyond. Marker labels indicate four-digit industries.

Close modal

With the treatment defined but before we turn to the econometrics, we report whether industries associated with a larger treatment experienced better export performance in the former Yugoslavian countries upon their return. Using only raw data, figure 4 visualizes the total value of exports of industries linked to different levels of treatment (i.e., quartiles), year after year. The figure shows until 1995 (the year where our “treatment” begins), industries in the four different quartiles had somewhat parallel trends. However, after 1995, the third and fourth quartiles in terms of treatment intensity diverge quite significantly from the first two quartiles. This visualization not only provides some descriptive evidence of the results holding with raw data, but also shows that the parallel trends assumption required for the difference-in-differences methodology is a reasonable one. In any event, we address pretrend issues more thoroughly in the next section.

Exports for Industries with Different Levels of Treatment

Figure 4.
Exports for Industries with Different Levels of Treatment

The figure plots the cumulative value of exports of the former Yugoslavia to the rest of the world (vertical axis) across years. Treatment is defined as the number of return migrants from Germany by 2000 as defined in the text.

Figure 4.
Exports for Industries with Different Levels of Treatment

The figure plots the cumulative value of exports of the former Yugoslavia to the rest of the world (vertical axis) across years. Treatment is defined as the number of return migrants from Germany by 2000 as defined in the text.

Close modal

C. Summary Statistics

Table 1 presents the summary statistics. In our sample are 786 industries, and since we use two points in time for the differences-in-differences estimation, the initial empirical analysis will use up to 1,572 observations. The table presents summary statistics for the main variables in the regression. The first two lines of the table present data for the average export value from former Yugoslavian countries to the rest of the world in the years 1990 and 2005, all in million U.S. dollars (note that we do not adjust these values for inflation, which is accounted for by our year fixed effect). These two points in time are the ones used in the main specification, which correspond to years before and after the war. However, we also present results for a multiperiod analysis as well that uses export data for all the years in between.

Table 1.

Summary Statistics

VariableNMeanSDMinMax
Exports YUG in 1990, 786 12.472 31.65 0.0 395.0 
million USD 
Exports YUG in 2005, 786 24.458 71.62 0.0 1,090.0 
million USD 
YUG workers 1991–1995 786 74.025 190.78 0.0 2,018.7 
YUG workers 1991–1995 786 21.639 60.61 0.0 778.5 
and out by 2000 
VariableNMeanSDMinMax
Exports YUG in 1990, 786 12.472 31.65 0.0 395.0 
million USD 
Exports YUG in 2005, 786 24.458 71.62 0.0 1,090.0 
million USD 
YUG workers 1991–1995 786 74.025 190.78 0.0 2,018.7 
YUG workers 1991–1995 786 21.639 60.61 0.0 778.5 
and out by 2000 

This table presents the sample summary statistics for the variables used to estimate specification (1).

Table 1 also summarizes the treatment. The third row in the table presents statistics for the number of sampled workers with Yugoslavian passport that joined the German labor force at some point between 1991 and 1995. The average industry had 74 Yugoslavian workers who, arguably, arrived at Germany because of the war and joined the labor force. The next row is a subset of that group and corresponds to our main treatment variable: the number of workers with Yugoslavian passport who had joined the German labor force sometime between 1991 and 1995 and had dropped from it by the year 2000. The value for this variable, averaged across all industries, is 21.6. Our treatment exploits variation across industries, which we see in the table varies from 0 to 778.21 All in all, our treatment is based on roughly 17,000 Yugoslavian workers across all industries, representative of the actual distribution.22

Note that our sample of Yugoslavians employed in the tradable industry shows that the rate of return was roughly 30%, substantially lower than the anecdotical 75% figure, which applies to the Yugoslavian refugee population as a whole (UNHCR, 2005; Ruhl & Lederer, 2001; Lederer, 1997). This discrepancy, however, poses no problem for our identification strategy as long as the rate of return is not biased toward certain industries, which we discuss in section IIID. Also note that despite presenting the summary statistics in nominal values, unless otherwise stated, all right-hand-side variables are rescaled using the inverse hyperbolic sine for estimation purposes.

D. Empirical Strategy

Our objective is to study changes in industry-level Yugoslavian exports to the rest of the world given different levels of treatment. We do this through a difference-in-differences estimation. Our baseline results are estimated through the following difference-in-differences specification,
(1)
where subscripts p and t represent industry and year, respectively. The left-hand-side variable (exportsp,t) measures the value of exports from the former Yugoslavia to the rest of the world excluding Germany for industry p during year t.

The variable of interest, treatp, is the treatment as explained above, which corresponds to the number of likely returning refugees for industry p, according to the definition detailed earlier. Given the fat-tailed distribution of this variable, we rescale it using the inverse hyperbolic sine, which behaves similar to a log transformation but has the benefit of being defined at 0. The interpretation of regression estimators in the form of the inverse hyperbolic sine is similar to the interpretation of a log-transformed variable (see MacKinnon & Magee, 1990).

We estimate this regression using two periods: “before,” which corresponds to 1990, just before the war started, and “after,” which corresponds to 2005, five years after most Yugoslavian refugees had returned.23 Thus, aftert is a dummy variable that equals 1 for the observations corresponding to the second period.

As for the other terms, ηp represents industry fixed effects while αt represents year fixed effects. The two fixed effects are perfectly multicollinear with the terms treatp and aftert, and so there is no need to add the interacted terms separately. ɛp,t represents the error term. Our estimations cluster standard errors at the industry level, the level at which the treatment varies (Besley & Burgess, 2004; Bertrand et al., 2004).

Given the fact that the left-hand side is calculated in U.S. dollars, we are required to use a monotonic transformation to deal with the fat-tailed distribution. All of our results are presented using three different transformations: log(exportsp,t), log(exportsp,t+1), and asinh(exportsp,t). The first one is undefined for values where exportsp,t=0, and therefore, when using log(exportsp,t) as the dependent variable, the sample size is reduced. The two other transformations deal with the occasions where exportsp,t=0 by either adding US$1 before the transformation or by computing instead the inverse hyperbolic sine (asinh), respectively.24 Given these monotonic log-type transformations, βDID represents the elasticity of exports to returnee workers. That is, industries with a 1% larger pool of returnee workers have larger export value by βDID percent larger between the before and after periods compared to industries with no returnee workers. Bear in mind that since this is a difference-in-difference setting, our results reflect relative differences in levels across industries based on their exposure to the treatment.

Our identification relies on the exogeneity of arrival and exit of refugees into and out of the German labor force with regard to industry-level export trends back in Yugoslavia. There are two main endogeneity concerns: the possibility that upon arrival, refugees self-selected into particular tradable sectors after anticipating their future postwar growth potential in Yugoslavia and the possibility that the exit of refugees from the German labor force by year 2000—even if it was enforced by across-the-board repatriation efforts by the German authorities—happened more or less frequently in particular industries in a way that is correlated with export dynamics in Yugoslavia. We address each of these possible endogeneity concerns below.

Self-selection into industries upon arrival.

In order to deal with the possibility that migrants self-selected into particular industries in a way that correlates with future Yugoslavian exports, we construct an instrumental variable that estimates the share of asylum seekers working in each industry by exploiting a spatial dispersal policy. While asylum requests were being processed, asylum seekers were sent to different parts of the country following the Königstein State Convention (Königsteiner Staatsabkommen) which was signed in 1949 by all German federal states and defined cost-sharing rules between states in jointly financed projects. The dispersal of asylum seekers is regulated at the federal level by the Asylum Procedure Act (Asylverfahrensgesetz), where each state is allocated a certain number of asylum seekers according to its “Königstein” quota (Königsteiner Schlüssel). The quota is based on the weighted sum of population (one-third) and tax revenues (two-thirds), and is recalculated annually. For example, Nordrhein-Westfalen is the state that should have received the largest numbers of asylum seekers in 1995, followed by Bayern and Baden-Württemberg, while states such as Bremen and Saarland received a very small share.

Our identification strategy is based on the premise that this allocation was exogenous to the Yugoslavian asylum seekers entering the country and, furthermore, to the future dynamics of Yugoslavian exports. In practice, an asylum seeker into the German territory is absorbed by a reception center in the state of arrival if there is any remaining capacity to receive more people, according to the quota described above; alternatively, the person is allocated to the reception center in a different state with the most vacancies according to the quota. The residence obligation ends as soon as asylum is granted. The average duration of the application procedure was between six months and two years.25

To construct the instrument, we combine two pieces of data: (i) the yearly asylum quotas for German states averaged between 1991 and 199526 and (ii) the relative size in terms of employment for each industry and state in 1990 (using German workers only), before the arrival of the refugees.27 The resulting variable can be used to estimate the share of Yugoslavian asylum seekers working in each industry nationwide. The following equation reflects the calculation:
The instrumental variable is a feasible one under two conditions: if it correlates with the treatment and if the exclusion restriction holds. In terms of the first condition, we see a strong correlation between the treatment and the instrumental variable (as shown in the first-stage results in table 2 or displayed as raw correlations in online appendix B).
Table 2.

Difference-in-Difference Estimation

OLS2SLS
log(exp)log(exp + 1)asinh(exp)log(exp)log(exp + 1)asinh(exp)
Dependent variable: exportsp,t 
treat2000 × after2005 0.087 0.135 0.137 0.124 0.159 0.161 
 (0.037)** (0.062)** (0.064)** (0.042)*** (0.054)*** (0.055)*** 
Observations 1,496 1,572 1,572 1,496 1,572 1,572 
KP F-Stat    19.85 19.97 19.97 
First stage, dependent variable: treatp×aftert((( 
treatIV × after2005    898.946 928.978 928.978 
    (201.753)*** (207.878)*** (207.878)*** 
Observations    1,496 1,572 1,572 
R2    0.79 0.78 0.78 
OLS2SLS
log(exp)log(exp + 1)asinh(exp)log(exp)log(exp + 1)asinh(exp)
Dependent variable: exportsp,t 
treat2000 × after2005 0.087 0.135 0.137 0.124 0.159 0.161 
 (0.037)** (0.062)** (0.064)** (0.042)*** (0.054)*** (0.055)*** 
Observations 1,496 1,572 1,572 1,496 1,572 1,572 
KP F-Stat    19.85 19.97 19.97 
First stage, dependent variable: treatp×aftert((( 
treatIV × after2005    898.946 928.978 928.978 
    (201.753)*** (207.878)*** (207.878)*** 
Observations    1,496 1,572 1,572 
R2    0.79 0.78 0.78 

This table shows results of the estimation for specification (1) using different monotonic transformations for exportsp,t in each column. The estimation uses average exports for years 1988 to 1990 in the before period and average exports for years 2005 to 2007 in the after period. The first three columns report results from an OLS estimation, while the last three columns report results from a 2SLS estimation. The lower panel presents the results of the first-stage estimation when appropriate. All columns include industry fixed effects and year fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at the industry level presented in parentheses. *p<0.10, **p<0.05, and ***p<0.01.

There are two main reasons for which this strong correlation between the instrument and the endogenous variable is not surprising. First, the geographic allocation of asylum seekers is relevant for all refugees who request asylum, even if the asylum request turns out not to be approved. That is, all refugees who eventually got a Duldung status but who originally requested asylum had to comply with this exogenous geographic allocation while their asylum status was being reviewed by the authorities. Second, the exogenous allocation of the share of Yugoslavians who actually requested asylum might as well be explanatory of the location choice of those who received Duldung even if they did not request asylum to begin with due to pull factors induced by migrant networks.

Our main assumption regarding the second condition—the exclusion restriction—is that both the quota of asylum seekers per state and year (defined by the German federal authorities), as well as the relative size of industries in Germany in 1990, are not correlated with future industry-specific export trends of former Yugoslavian countries to the rest of the world other than through the migrants themselves. We have no reason to think that this assumption could be violated.28

Self-selection out of industries upon exit.

The other remaining concern is that the exit of Yugoslavian Duldung holders from the German labor force was endogenous. For example, if workers left the labor force more massively in some industries than in others, in a way that correlates with their future export potential in Yugoslavia, then this could invalidate our identification strategy.

This was not the case, as shown in figure 5. The figure compares the proportion of Yugoslavians who arrived between 1991 and 1995 working in each four-digit SITC industry on the vertical axis, against the proportion of Yugoslavian who had returned by 2000 (based on the definition of the treatment) for each industry on the horizontal axis. The dashed line represents the 45 degree line. If exit from the labor force by Yugoslavians was completely random, we would see a perfect alignment of those dots along the 45 degree line: the share of workers entering each industry must be the same as the share of workers leaving it. Barring some exceptions, the graph does approximate this scenario. In fact, the correlation between both shares is close to 0.9.

Share of Arrival versus Exit from the German Labor Force by Industry
Figure 5.
Share of Arrival versus Exit from the German Labor Force by Industry

The figure plots the share of Yugoslavian workers in each industry out of the total that joined the labor force between 1991 and 1995 on the vertical axis against the share of Yugoslavian workers in each industry out of the total who dropped out of the labor force by 2000 (according to the way we define the treatment).

Figure 5.
Share of Arrival versus Exit from the German Labor Force by Industry

The figure plots the share of Yugoslavian workers in each industry out of the total that joined the labor force between 1991 and 1995 on the vertical axis against the share of Yugoslavian workers in each industry out of the total who dropped out of the labor force by 2000 (according to the way we define the treatment).

Close modal

Given that few observations seem to be outliers, we also compute the distance between each value in the plot and the 45 degree line and correlate it with the log-growth rate of Yugoslavian exports by industry between 1990 and 2005. We find small, negative, and statistically insignificant correlation coefficients across the board (-0.0295 when computing the growth using logs, and -0.0133 when computing growth using the inverse hyperbolic sine).

Finally, as a way to relieve possible concerns due to endogeneity with respect to exit, it is important to note that our results are robust to using the number of Yugoslavian refugees workers per industry in 1995, without the exit component, which directly addresses this concern (see online appendix table C1).

A. Baseline Results

Results for specification (1) are presented in table 2. The first three columns report results using an OLS estimation, while the last three columns report results using a 2SLS estimation, making use of the instrumental variable described in section IIID. The table reports results using log(exportsp,t), log(exportsp,t+1) and asinh(exportsp,t) as dependent variables. Since the regressor treatp is rescaled using the inverse hyperbolic sine transformation, which behaves similar to a log transformation, we interpret βDID as an elasticity.29

In the first three columns, we find all estimates to be positive and statistically different from 0 for all different monotonic transformations of the dependent variable. The standard errors are clustered at the industry level, which is the level of disaggregation of the treatment.

Column 1 of table 2 presents the estimates when using the natural logarithmic transformation for the dependent variable. The point estimate in the first column is about two-thirds the size of those in the other two columns. This is not surprising as the first column excludes zeros and therefore excludes instances in which industries are more likely to grow faster if they have a non-zero value in the second period. Yet this difference says something more: the fact that the point estimates in columns 2 and 3 are positive and significant, which include instances where an industry was inexistent in the export basket of Yugoslavia by 1995, and are larger than the point estimate in column 1, implies that the effect of return migration on comparative advantage is valid at the extensive margin (e.g., opening a new line of exports) as well as at the intensive margin (e.g., growth of already existing export lines), along the lines of Bahar and Rapoport (2018). In either case, the results show that the elasticity of exports to return workers ranges from 0.09 to 0.14, depending on the transformation of the left-hand-side variable used (and, thus, on whether zeros are included).

Columns 4, 5, and 6 present the analogous 2SLS estimates (and the lower panel presents the corresponding first-stage estimations). For those columns, we also report the F-statistics, which measure the strength of the first stage; they are all above 14, so we can reject the possibility of weak instrumentation. The elasticities estimated through 2SLS are positive, statistically significant, and quite similar to the OLS results with point estimates that are only slightly larger. Given the standard errors, however, we cannot reject the hypothesis that the OLS and the 2SLS estimates are equal. Given the setting of the natural experiment and the use of an instrumental variable, we interpret these results as causal. Thus, based on the 2SLS results, we find that Yugoslavian industries that received 10% more return migrants from Germany (who worked in those same industries), exhibited higher exports by 1% to 1.6% during the period of the study. We show in online appendix section C.2.1 that our results are not sensitive to any particular industry.

Back-of-the-envelope calculations based on our sample size imply that returning refugees explain up to 6% of all Yugoslavian export growth between 1990 and 2005. In fact, since most of the export growth between 1990 and 2005 happens after the year 2000, most of this effect is concentrated between 2000 to 2005.30

In the presence of self-selection of workers we would expect results to decrease in magnitude once we instrument. What may then explain why the 2SLS estimates are in fact slightly larger than the OLS ones? One possible explanation is that the 2SLS estimation uses variation in the treatment that is disproportionately coming from refugees allocated to areas in Western Germany (and specifically western and southern German states) where the most productive firms (and workers) are located.

B. Event Study Estimation

Can our results be explained by a previous trend in exports? Given the availability of exports data across several years, we turn to estimate the effect of return migration in an event study setting. To account for the typical volatility of exports on a yearly basis, we perform the estimation using five-year averages for the dependent variable and estimate βDID for six different periods, from 1985–1989 to 2010–2014. To do this, we simply reestimate specification (1), this time substituting the dummy aftert for several dummies, each one signaling a time period, along the lines of Autor et al. (2003). We define 1990 to 1994 as the base period, and therefore the other point estimates are relative to it.

The estimation (using 2SLS) is summarized in figure 6, which shows in the upper panel the evolution of the expected value of exports (across our three different measures) by periods for two groups of industries: those for which the value of treatp equals 0, and those for which treatp equals 1 standard deviation of the treatment (denoted by σ). The figures in the lower panel show the difference between the two groups, and it can be seen how the effect becomes positive and statistically significant starting in the period where the refugees start returning, 1995 to 1999. Note that based on the standard errors (as measured by the whiskers representing 95% confidence intervals), we cannot reject the hypothesis that the trends for both groups in periods before 1995 are statistically the same.

Event Study (2SLS), Five-Year Periods

Figure 6.
Event Study (2SLS), Five-Year Periods

The top panel plots exports over time for two groups: industries for which treatp equals 0 and for which treatp equals 1 standard deviation of the treatment. The dependent variable is the five-year average of exports (each column uses a different linear transformation and the period 1990 to 1994 is used as the base year). The bottom figure plots estimates for βDID for each five-year period, which corresponds to the difference between the two groups of industries plotted in the top panel. The results are estimated using 2SLS and include the convergence control. Ninety-five percent confidence intervals for the estimation are represented by the whiskers.

Figure 6.
Event Study (2SLS), Five-Year Periods

The top panel plots exports over time for two groups: industries for which treatp equals 0 and for which treatp equals 1 standard deviation of the treatment. The dependent variable is the five-year average of exports (each column uses a different linear transformation and the period 1990 to 1994 is used as the base year). The bottom figure plots estimates for βDID for each five-year period, which corresponds to the difference between the two groups of industries plotted in the top panel. The results are estimated using 2SLS and include the convergence control. Ninety-five percent confidence intervals for the estimation are represented by the whiskers.

Close modal

These findings suggest an important result: the marginal effect of return migration on the emergence of new exports becomes stronger over time. The figure also reveals that the average industry experiences a drop in export performance during the war as compared to the base period. Treated industries recover and reach back their 1990–1994 level in the 2000 to 2004 period (or even earlier, when using the log transformation), while nontreated ones recover later. In that sense, part of what our effect is capturing in the first few postconflict years is that treated industries, on average, shrunk less than nontreated ones.31

C. Falsification Test Using the Synthetic Control Method

Our main strategy compares different industry lines based on the intensity of the treatment. We complement those results with implementing the synthetic control method (Abadie & Gardeazabal, 2003; Abadie et al., 2010, 2015) in the context of our empirical strategy. In other words, we create a synthetic industry for every Yugoslavian industry that mimics export dynamics until 1995 (the year our treatment starts kicking in), based on over one hundred other countries. We use five main predictors to construct each synthetic industry, using data for the period 1986 to 1995: export value of the industry itself (only for years 1990, 1993, and 1995), its export share, and the export share of its corresponding one-digit SITC, as well as GDP per capita, and population size. We then apply the synth algorithm that computes a synthetic control for each industry based on a weighted combination of countries other than Yugoslavia (see Abadie et al., 2011).

Figure 7 visualizes the main results of this exercise, plotting the difference between the export value of the real and synthetic industries. The top panel shows the evolution of each one of these differences: until 1995, there is almost no difference between the real and synthetic industries, but after 1995, we see all types of dynamics. The bottom panel groups industries in two, averaging the difference between their real and synthetic export values: low treatment and high treatment, which corresponds to the first and fourth quartiles of the distribution of treatp as defined above (analogous to figure 4). The plot shows how, on average, real Yugoslavian industries outperform the synthetic ones, particularly among the high-treatment industries. Results using regression analysis are consistent and presented in online appendix C.3.

Difference in Export Value, Real versus Synthetic Industries

Figure 7.
Difference in Export Value, Real versus Synthetic Industries

The top panel presents the evolution of the difference in export value between real and synthetic for all industries in the data set. The bottom panel groups the differences in high versus low treatment (4th versus 1st quartile of the treatment) across years. Results are robust to the inclusion of a small number of outlier industries that were removed from this plot for visualization purposes.

Figure 7.
Difference in Export Value, Real versus Synthetic Industries

The top panel presents the evolution of the difference in export value between real and synthetic for all industries in the data set. The bottom panel groups the differences in high versus low treatment (4th versus 1st quartile of the treatment) across years. Results are robust to the inclusion of a small number of outlier industries that were removed from this plot for visualization purposes.

Close modal

There are a number of possible candidate explanations for our results, which we explore in this section.

A. Industry-Level Productivity Shifts

Our analysis that follows consistently suggests that the main driver of our results are productivity shifts caused by the inflows of returning workers, who were exposed to better practices and technologies while in Germany. This is supported by a number of tests, which we expand on below, as well as those in section VI, where we show that the workers driving our results are those with characteristics or occupations more likely to transfer knowledge, technology, best practices, and more that have the potential to shift productivity.

Industry-level Ricardian comparative advantage.

First, we note that our results are consistent when using an industry-level measure of comparative advantage, which in theory responds to productivity parameters. In practice, we reestimate our specification using as the dependent variable a Ricardian comparative advantage parameter for Yugoslavia (Φp,t), estimated following Costinot et al. (2012) and Leromain and Orefice (2014).32 Analogous to our baseline results, we use the same two different monotonic transformations for Φp,t (we skip the log(Φp,t+1) transformation since there are no zeros). Results are presented in table 3.

Table 3.

DID, Costinot et al. (2012) Measures in LHS

Dependent variable: Φp,t, based on Costinot et al. (2012)
OLS2SLS
log(Φ)asinh(Φ)log(Φ)asinh(Φ)
treat2000 × after2005 0.023 0.018 0.036 0.030 
 (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.004)*** (0.004)*** 
Observations 1,572 1,572 1,572 1,572 
KP F-statistic   19.97 19.97 
Dependent variable: Φp,t, based on Costinot et al. (2012)
OLS2SLS
log(Φ)asinh(Φ)log(Φ)asinh(Φ)
treat2000 × after2005 0.023 0.018 0.036 0.030 
 (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.004)*** (0.004)*** 
Observations 1,572 1,572 1,572 1,572 
KP F-statistic   19.97 19.97 

This table shows the results of the estimation for specification (1) using different monotonic transformations for Φp,t in each column. Φp,t is a measure that quantifies Ricardian comparative advantage estimated following Costinot et al. (2012). The first two columns report results from an OLS estimation, and the last two columns report results from a 2SLS estimation. All columns include industry fixed effects and year fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at the industry level are presented in parentheses. *p<0.10, **p<0.05, and ***p<0.01.

Labor productivity, wages, and industry size.

We replicate our main specification using production data from UNIDO for sectors in Yugoslavian countries (consistent with the main results, we aggregate all countries into a single one). We focus on outcomes such as output (production) per worker, value added per worker, and average wage, all in U.S. dollars. As opposed to the exports data used above, having the number of employees per sector allows us to compute outputs relative to the size of the sector. The data have complete information for only eighteen two-digit ISIC sectors, and as such we are limited to a low number of observations, which we acknowledge is a limitation of this test. We merge these data to the treatment variable, which was a trivial task given the one-to-one correspondence between ISIC/NACE and W93 sector classifications.

Results of OLS estimations based on the main specification are presented in table 4, panel A. Columns 1 and 2 use as dependent variable measures of labor productivity, output (production) per worker and value added per worker, while column 3 uses as dependent variable the average wage of the sector, which also proxies for labor productivity of the sector as a whole. The results are consistent with the idea that productivity shifts are a central mechanism behind our main findings. Sectors with 10% more returnees tend to be 0.9% to 1.1% more productive depending on the measure used.

Table 4.

DID, Outcomes from UNIDO

A: UNIDO data
asinh(prodpw)asinh(vaddpw)asinh(wage)
treat2000 × after2005 0.109 0.088 0.091 
 (0.035)*** (0.020)*** (0.037)** 
Observations 36 36 36 
R2 0.92 0.89 0.81 
B: Bosnian Data((( 
 asinh(exppw)((( asinh(firmsasinh(workers
treatBIH2000 × after2010 0.830 0.360 0.275 
 (0.388)** (0.172)** (0.094)*** 
Observations 44 44 44 
R2 0.84 0.82 0.65 
A: UNIDO data
asinh(prodpw)asinh(vaddpw)asinh(wage)
treat2000 × after2005 0.109 0.088 0.091 
 (0.035)*** (0.020)*** (0.037)** 
Observations 36 36 36 
R2 0.92 0.89 0.81 
B: Bosnian Data((( 
 asinh(exppw)((( asinh(firmsasinh(workers
treatBIH2000 × after2010 0.830 0.360 0.275 
 (0.388)** (0.172)** (0.094)*** 
Observations 44 44 44 
R2 0.84 0.82 0.65 

Panel A shows results of the estimation for specification (1), focusing only on outcomes of production and wages using data from UNIDO for former Yugoslavian republics combined, using variation of two-digit sectors. Column 1 uses output or production per worker as the dependent variable, column 2 uses value added per worker, and column 3 uses average wages, all in U.S. dollars and transformed using the inverse hyperbolic sine. Panel B shows results of the estimation for specification (1), focusing only on outcomes for the Bosnian economy, using variation of two-digit sectors. Column 1 uses exports per worker in U.S. dollars as the dependent variable, column 2 uses number of firms, and column 3 uses number of workers, all transformed using the inverse hyperbolic sine. All columns include sector fixed effects and year fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at the industry level presented in parentheses. *p<0.10, **p<0.05, and ***p<0.01.

We were able to collect and digitize a number of sector-level indicators for the Republic of Bosnia and Herzegovina (the country with the largest number of refugees hosted by Germany) before and after the war. In particular, we gather sectoral data for export values, number of firms, and number of workers for the years 1990 and 2010 (the latter being the first postwar year for which such data are available). The sources of our collection are the Statistical Almanac (Statisticki Godisnjak) and the Structural Business Statistics reports (Strukturne Poslovne Statistike) published by the Statistical Agency of Bosnia and Herzegovina (Agencija za Statistiku BiH).

Given that these data are particularly for Bosnia and Herzegovina, we use our main data source to construct variations of the treatment meant to capture more precisely the number of Bosnian returning refugees (as opposed to Yugoslavians in general). In particular, we count workers who had been registered as having a Bosnian passport at some point during their stay in Germany and who had arrived sometime between 1991 and 1995 and had left by 2000. Note that while some of these workers entered the German labor force as Bosnian nationals, others obtained Bosnian citizenship during their stay in Germany and reported it.33 We link this treatment to the outcomes described by sector relying on the equivalence between the German classification WZ 93 (the format for the treatment data) and the two-digit NACE sectoral classification (the format for the Bosnian data we collected). We end up for with a sample of 22 sectors and 44 observations (using data for each sector in 1990 and 2005). Similar to the previous results, we acknowledge that the small number of observations poses a limitation for these particular results.

Consistent with previous estimations, we transform all the variables using the inverse hyperbolic sine and based our estimations on specification (1). Table 4, panel B, presents the OLS results using the treatment variable described above. Column 1 presents estimates when using Bosnian exports per worker as the dependent variable (in U.S. dollars), while columns 2 and 3 estimate the effect of the treatment on the number of firms and the number of workers per sector, respectively. The point estimates are positive and significant, implying that a higher number of returnees translates into higher labor productivity, as proxied by exports per worker, as well as sectors that are larger in terms of both firms and workers. We note that the point estimates are particularly high compared to our baseline results, but since these results are for Bosnia only, and not for Yugoslavia as a whole, a comparison is possible to only a limited extent. Moreover, a simple look at the coefficients suggest that on average, the treated sectors end up having firms that are smaller in terms of workers, which is typically the case for new firms. Consistently, there is rich anecdotal evidence on the creation of new firms by returnees, some of which we compile in online appendix section A.

B. Alternative Explanations

We go through a number of alternative explanations of our results, other than productivity shifts, that we are able to rule out, to the best of our ability. It is important to mention, however, that for any variable to be an alternative explanation in our empirical setting, it must comply with one important condition: that it can systematically explain cross-industry variation in export dynamics in ways that also correlate with the treatment variable (or in 2SLS specifications with our instrument). To the extent that alternative explanations do not comply with this condition, accounting for them won’t result in results that are very different from the main ones.

There are four alternative explanations that we rule out:

  1. Scale effects: Workers returning simply are able to produce—and thus export—more quantity. For more details on how we address these concerns, see online appendix section C.4.1.

  2. Convergence in structural transformation: Our effects are being driven by pure “convergence” in terms of structural transformation such that Yugoslavia’s productive structure in the late 2000s reflects that of Germany in the early 1990s. This concern is addressed in online appendix section C.4.2. Note that the results using the synthetic controls presented in section IVC address this concern too.

  3. Capital and investment: Returning refugees are going into industries that are experiencing capital inflows, simultaneously, and our results are indeed explained by the latter. We address these concerns in online appendix section C.4.3.

  4. Bilateral transaction trade costs: Our results are being driven by possible reductions of transaction costs of exporting to Germany caused by migrant networks. For more details on how we address this concern, see online appendix section C.4.4.

The findings of the previous section point to productivity shifts as the main driver of export performance in the context of our results. This section complements those findings by digging into the data to study the role of the different characteristics and occupations of the returning refugees in our sample in driving our results. If indeed productivity shifts are behind our results, we should find that the treatment effect is particularly driven by certain workers more likely to transfer knowledge, technologies, and best practices. To do so, we expand specification (1) and rewrite it as
where each term treatp,i corresponds the total number of returning Yugoslavians in each category i in terms of workers’ characteristics. All other terms remain the same as in specification (1). We present results using characteristics grouped in six categories:
  1. Skilled versus unskilled workers based on their education levels. As unskilled, we define workers without postsecondary education and skilled as workers with education beyond high school, including vocational training, college degree or more. Since education does not devalue, we simply use the highest educational information attached to each worker at any point during the period of observation.

  2. We distinguish migrants with occupations intensive in manual tasks versus occupations intensive in analytical and cognitive tasks, using the classification provided by Dengler et al. (2014), which formalizes German occupations into five task categories, similar to Autor et al. (2003).

  3. We classify occupations as low skilled and high skilled based on Blossfeld’s (1987) classification of professions. For example, high-skilled occupations include managerial ones as well as professionals (e.g., engineers, lawyers, technicians, accountants, lab technicians), and low-skilled occupations as, for example, drivers, carpenters, and textile processing operatives.

  4. We distinguish workers by the supervisory intensity of their occupation based on the German Qualifications and Career Survey (BIBB/BAuA) of 1999. In particular we use the workers’ responses regarding their supervisory status (based on the answer to the question: “Do you have coworkers for whom you are the direct supervisor?”) and assign to each occupation both the share of workers who self-report acting as supervisors and the share of those who report the opposite.34

  5. We distinguish workers based on whether they worked in the top 25% paying firms in terms of average wages or in the bottom 75% paying firms. Typically, top-paying firms are the most productive ones by being able to attract the best workers and innovating or adopting innovations that help workers be more productive.

  6. We distinguish workers based on the average growth in their wage during their stay in Germany as proxy for productivity improvements. We separate workers within each industry into two groups: workers with wage growth (based on the compound average growth rate, CAGR) below median and those with wage growth above the median, based on all returnees in our treatment.

The summary of our results is presented in table 5.35 Each column presents results using a different monotonic transformation of the dependent variable, consistent with all previous results in the paper. Columns show the estimated value of βiDID for each of the constructed treatments belonging to each of the categories described above (we only present results using OLS, as we don’t have instruments for more than one endogenous variable at a time).

Table 5.

DID, Workers’ Education and Occupations

βDIDlog(exp)log(exp + 1)asinh(exp)
Total 0.087** 0.135** 0.137** 
 (0.037) (0.062) (0.064) 
Unskilled -0.292 -0.201 -0.197 
 (0.126) (0.145) (0.147) 
Skilled 0.421*** 0.377*** 0.375** 
 (0.132) (0.145) (0.146) 
Manual 0.023 0.076 0.078 
 (0.053) (0.073) (0.075) 
Analytical/cognitive 0.139* 0.131* 0.131* 
 (0.074) (0.076) (0.076) 
Low-skill profession 0.012 0.069 0.071 
 (0.064) (0.093) (0.096) 
High-skill profession 0.114 0.104 0.104 
 (0.070) (0.076) (0.077) 
Nonsupervisor -0.030 0.023 0.023 
 (0.109) (0.179) (0.185) 
Supervisor 0.184 0.179 0.181 
 (0.136) (0.202) (0.208) 
Low-paying firm -0.027 0.032 0.034 
 (0.059) (0.078) (0.079) 
High-paying firm 0.152** 0.143* 0.142* 
 (0.066) (0.079) (0.081) 
Slow-growth wage -0.089 -0.054 -0.052 
 (0.200) (0.203) (0.204) 
Fast-growth wage 0.180 0.207 0.207 
 (0.198) (0.207) (0.208) 
βDIDlog(exp)log(exp + 1)asinh(exp)
Total 0.087** 0.135** 0.137** 
 (0.037) (0.062) (0.064) 
Unskilled -0.292 -0.201 -0.197 
 (0.126) (0.145) (0.147) 
Skilled 0.421*** 0.377*** 0.375** 
 (0.132) (0.145) (0.146) 
Manual 0.023 0.076 0.078 
 (0.053) (0.073) (0.075) 
Analytical/cognitive 0.139* 0.131* 0.131* 
 (0.074) (0.076) (0.076) 
Low-skill profession 0.012 0.069 0.071 
 (0.064) (0.093) (0.096) 
High-skill profession 0.114 0.104 0.104 
 (0.070) (0.076) (0.077) 
Nonsupervisor -0.030 0.023 0.023 
 (0.109) (0.179) (0.185) 
Supervisor 0.184 0.179 0.181 
 (0.136) (0.202) (0.208) 
Low-paying firm -0.027 0.032 0.034 
 (0.059) (0.078) (0.079) 
High-paying firm 0.152** 0.143* 0.142* 
 (0.066) (0.079) (0.081) 
Slow-growth wage -0.089 -0.054 -0.052 
 (0.200) (0.203) (0.204) 
Fast-growth wage 0.180 0.207 0.207 
 (0.198) (0.207) (0.208) 

This table shows the results of the OLS estimation for specification (1) using treatments constructed by aggregating workers by groups based on their skills and/or occupations. The table presents OLS estimations. Each group of results uses different monotonic transformations for exportsp,t in different columns. All columns include the convergence control, as well as industry fixed effects and year fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at the industry level are presented in parentheses. *p<0.10, **p<0.05, and ***p<0.01.

The first row replicates the main results using the total number of returnees per industry, for comparison purposes. Overall, based on the size of point estimates, results reveal that our findings are particularly driven by workers with higher educational attainment (skilled), workers in occupations that are intensive in analytical tasks (as opposed to manual ones), workers in skilled occupations (as opposed to unskilled ones), and workers in supervisory occupations. We also find that the results are particularly driven by workers who worked in the top-paying firms during their stay in Germany and find that workers for whom wages grew faster during their stay in Germany correlate with a higher export performance. Note that while some of these results are statistically significant (namely, skilled workers, occupations intensive in analytical and cognitive tasks, and workers in high-paying firms), while the other point estimates are less precise.

Note, however, that the point estimates are to be interpreted in terms of elasticity and thus ultimately, the marginal effect of one worker belonging to each of the categories driving the results is much larger than what the point estimate suggests. This is because the types of workers driving the results are a smaller share of all workers when looking at the within-industry composition of workers in the sample. The idea that a small number of workers can have such an important effect on exports of a whole industry in such little time might seem implausible at first, but some anecdotal evidence documented by others seems to strongly support that idea. For instance, Rhee and Belot (1990) and Easterly (2001) document the story of the success of the garment sector in Bangladesh. Between 1980 and 1986, the share of garments in Bangladesh’s total exports rose from 0.5% to 28.3%. The unprecedented take-off of the garment export sector is often attributed to 130 Bangladeshi workers—only four of them in management positions—who spent eight months in 1979 working and being trained in Korea as part of an agreement between their company, Desh of Bangladesh, and the Korean firm Daewoo. The know-how acquired by these workers seems to have been crucial in making Desh a highly successful exporter firm. Perhaps more important, such know-how eventually spilled over as workers moved to other firms or created new ones, contributing to the massive success of garment exports as one of Bangladesh’s most significant export sectors.

In this context, we believe our findings pointing to productive knowledge and managerial know-how as the main mechanisms driving the export dynamics, as well as the magnitudes of the coefficients we report, are aligned with other studies in the literature.

The Balkan wars of the early 1990s created massive forced displacement from and within the former Yugoslavia. Most internationally displaced refugees ended up in Germany, where they could work under temporary protection status. A majority of them eventually returned home after the Dayton peace agreement of December 1995 and the repatriations that followed. We exploit this natural experiment that resulted in exposure to German industrial know-how, technology, and best practices, to investigate the role of returning refugees in explaining the export performance of their home countries. Using confidential German social security data, we find that Yugoslavian exports performed significantly better during the postwar period in industries that returnees had worked in while in Germany. Furthermore, we find that productivity is the underlying mechanism driving export performance in our setting. This is backed by the fact that our results are particularly driven by returnees with characteristics and in occupations more likely to generate productivity improvements.

Our results contribute to a burgeoning literature that emphasizes that migrants can serve as drivers of the diffusion of knowledge, technologies, and best practices resulting in productivity shifts. To the best of our knowledge, we are first to find such evidence using a natural experiment, especially in a context of returning forced migration.

In terms of policy implications, our results speak to the importance of allowing refugees full labor integration in their receiving countries. This is not only for the obvious reasons of the benefits to local hosting communities, but also because of how such policy can be a crucial determinant of the reconstruction of their home countries upon their eventual return.

More generally, the ability of a worker to become more productive has to do with his or her accumulated experience and his or her ability to learn from others while on the job. Migration therefore is an important vehicle in the process of knowledge transfers across locations.36

Better understanding this process and identifying channels through which these dynamics occur, such as the policy and institutional environments that facilitate the diffusion of knowledge through migration, are important missing pieces in the literature and an active part of our future research agenda.

1

See Becker and Ferrara (2019) for a comprehensive literature review on the economic consequences of forced displacement.

2

Previous studies have focused on the role that return migrants play (mostly through capital accumulation while abroad) in explaining small-scale entrepreneurship. Rapoport and Docquier (2006) provide a review of this literature. Yet our paper differs from these other studies as we document large-scale effects on industry-level outcomes driven by productivity, as opposed to small-scale effects driven by capital accumulation.

3

Our results also relate to the determinants of postconflict reconstruction literature in general, using the case of former Yugoslavian countries (Black, 2001; Black & Gent, 2006).

4

See Angrist and Kugler (2003) for a summary of the migration of Yugoslavian nationals to different European destinations (in the context of a study on the impact on local labor markets).

5

It is important to note, however, that while we refer to Yugoslavians fleeing the civil conflict as “refugees” throughout this paper, we are using the term loosely, as most of them did not receive formal refugee status by Germany (as we explain below), which is the outcome of a legal process that is considered on a case-by-case basis according to the definitions agreed on and stated in the Geneva Convention on Refugees of 1951 and the Protocol Relating to the Status of Refugees of 1967 (among other country- or region-specific definitions). Despite the exact legal definitions, throughout the paper, we often use the words refugees and migrants interchangeably to refer to the same people.

6

In the early 1990s, as a response to the legal difficulties faced by the hundreds of thousands of refugees seeking protection, of whom almost none were eligible for asylum, the German government applied this status on a large scale. In principle, from 1993 onward there existed a legal status for civil war refugees, which granted temporary protection without a case-by-case assessment, but this status was not applied until 1999 because federal and state governments could not agree on distributing the costs. The Duldung status was also granted relatively quickly, making it possible for Germany to process large numbers of arrivals. Compared to other European countries, this was a considerable humanitarian gesture on the part of the German government (Dimova, 2006; Lederer, 1997).

7

Labor market access conditions for asylum seekers and Duldung holders changed a few times. Until 1991, immediate access to the labor market was possible. Between 1991 and 1997, they could apply for a general work permit and with an additional waiting period of three months for asylum seekers. Modifications in the law in 1997 further restricted access to the labor market. This changed again in 2001 when one-year waiting time was introduced. For details, see Liedtke (2002).

8

The rules on mobility while the application was being processed were defined by local governments. Some states restricted movement of the asylum seeker to a district, while others allowed free mobility within the state.

9

For the Croatians, however, the deportations started following the signature of the cease-fire agreement known as the Vance Plan in January 1992. By the end of 1994, almost all of the Croatian refugees had returned (Lederer, 1997).

10

Voluntary returns were mainly realized as a part of the program of German government through REAG (Program for Reintegration and Emigration for Claimants of Asylum in Germany) and GARP (Government Program of Assistance to Repatriation), which was implemented in cooperation with the International Organization for Migration (IOM) whose target was to support voluntary return. Both programs were completed in 2001 (Nenadic et al., 2005).

11

These numbers are confirmed when looking at the return rates with respect to the different nationalities and ethnicities involved in the conflict. For example, when it comes to Bosnian refugees, Rühl and Lederer (2001, 50) write that “the number of Bosnian war refugees fell from 345,000 to approximately 28,000 by December 2000, more than 260,000 of which went voluntarily to Bosnia-Herzegovina. About 51,000 have migrated on to other countries (to the USA, Canada and Australia). The proportion of forced repatriations is well below 2% (approximately 5,500 cases).”

12

Social networks have also be shown to affect aggregate economic outcomes (Burchardi & Hassan, 2013).

13

These records have been assembled by the Institute of Employment Research (IAB) into the Employment History (BeH) data file (IAB, 2015). The data or variants of it have been widely used to study a variety of labor market aspects (Card et al., 2013; Dustmann & Glitz, 2015; Dustmann et al., 2017).

14

For privacy issues, the sample used in this paper is an anonymized version of the original database. In order to comply with data privacy rules, sensitive values—industry-period observations with fewer than 20 workers—have been replaced with different moments of the distribution of the number of migrant workers in the same industry and year. The number of cells affected depends of course on the level of disaggregation of worker characteristics such as education, occupation, and skill. More details on this procedure can be provided on request. The results presented here, however, are robust to using the nonanonymized version instead.

15

Using our employment sample, we compute the number of workers in Germany by nationality and year for all SITC four-digit industry categories. We use the nationality of the worker based on the passport recorded at his or her first appearance in the database. To compute the number of workers by industry we rely on the concordance tables produced by the United Nations Statistical Office and the work by Dauth et al. (2014) that matches German three-digit WZ industry codes to four-digit SITC (rev. 2) industries. When match is one-to-many, we create our own concordance following the same procedure as Cuñat and Melitz (2012) described in their footnote 24. In particular, we use the distribution of German exports in 1995 as a proxy for the distribution of employment across different four-digit SITC industries that correspond to a single three-digit WZ German industry. Further details on the employment sample, variable descriptions, and auxiliary data are provided in online appendix section B.

16

Very few people left Slovenia while almost none left the FYR of Macedonia as both countries obtained their independence with limited or no armed conflict. While Slovenia was the republic with highest GDP per capita and a much more diversified export basket than the rest of the countries to begin with, Macedonia was one of the poorest republics of the former Yugoslavia with few exports. Our results are robust to excluding both Slovenia and Macedonia from the exports data (see online appendix section C.2.4).

17

About 10% of the Yugoslavian workers we see entering the labor force between 1991 and 1995 were 18 years or younger on the year of entry. In contrast, 75% were 20 or older and 50% were 25 or older. This rules out the possibility that the entry of Yugoslavian into the labor force is mostly driven by locals with Yugoslavian passports joining the labor force at a young age rather than by refugees arriving to Germany.

18

Finding no entry for a person in our data implies that this person was not employed in any job, industry, or occupation subject to social security contributions on June 30 of any given year.

19

Our data also show that about half of these Yugoslavian workers who arrived between 1991 and 1995 are still active in the German labor force by 2014. Presumably, these “stayers” were not Duldung holders (and therefore, were not subject to deportation). Some of them could have been holders but were allowed to stay for humanitarian reasons.

20

However, when focusing on those migrants we can identify in our data as Bosnians, even though they are a smaller share, the dropout rate of the labor force is more than 50%, closer to the global official figures.

21

Noninteger number of workers in an industry is a result of the use of weights based on industry code concordances during the data construction stage. For more information see online appendix section B.

22

Between 1991 and 1995, 210,000 Yugoslavian workers appear the first time in our data. If the total flow was of 700,000 people, it is reasonable that about half of them were of working age. Our sample is, of course, smaller than the total population; thus the 210,000 figure seems reasonable. Of the 210,000 in our sample, 35% (or 75,000 workers) had exited the sample before the year 2000. Of those, roughly 75,000, only 22% (around 17,000 workers) had a job in tradable industries during the 1990s.

23

More precisely, we use average exports per industry between 1988 and 1990 for the before period, and the average between 2005 and 2007 for the after period, given the high volatility of yearly export data. Our results, however, are robust to using only data for the actual years for which the before and after periods are defined: 1990 and 2005.

24

Since exports are aggregated across all destinations, the number of zeroes in the data is not as large as when using bilateral trade data. We explore this in detail in online appendix section C.1.

25

Concerns might remain given that the geographic allocation of refugees is exogenous conditional on the reception center at the port of arrival being at full capacity. However, in online appendix section C.2.3, we present results using an instrument that excludes the most common ports of arrivals in the calculation and find them to be robust to our main results.

26

In fact, since we don’t have data pre-1995 for states of East Germany, we set those at 0 for 1991 to 1994. However, it turns out that this lack of variation is not critical. According to the employment data, in 1995 there were over 367,000 Yugoslavians employed in West German states across all industries, as compared to only 1,400 in East Germany, or just 0.38%. Thus, that lack of variation should not affect the relevance of our instrument.

27

We are aware of the critique by Jaeger et al. (2018) regarding using past spatial distributions of migrants to instrument for current distribution, though in our paper, it lacks relevance given that our dependent variable does not reflect economic activity in the same location of the migrants’ destination but rather in their country of origin.

28

One possible violation for this exclusion restriction is convergence in terms of structural transformation: Yugoslavia in the 2000s moved toward industries that were large in Germany in 1990. In robustness tests detailed below (and expanded on in online appendix section C.4.2) we rule out this possibility by including the relevant controls in the baseline specification.

29

The continuous character of our treatment implies, arguably, that our estimator can be characterized as a fuzzy differences-in-differences one (see De Chaisemartin & D’Haultfoeuille, 2018). In our setting, the “control” group is stable over time (e.g., there are no control group “switchers”), which implies our estimation only relies on the common trends assumption. In other words, our setting allows us not to require the “stable treatment over time” or the “homogeneous treatment effect between groups” assumptions (assumptions 5 and 6 in De Chaisemartin & D’Haultfoeuille, 2018). While relaxing assumption 5 in our setting is straightforward, doing the same with assumption 6 might not be. Thus, as a robustness test, we compute the Wald DID estimator following De Chaisemartin and D’Haultfoeuille (2018), defining the treated units as those above the 25th percentile in terms of treatment intensity. We find our results reassuring: the Wald DID point estimates are between 0.15 and 0.28, depending on the monotonic transformation used, and are all statistically significant at the 10% level. The point estimates are slightly larger than the OLS ones reported in table 2, but they all fall within the statistical margin of error of the estimators. We thank Clement De Chaisemartin for his guidance on this exercise.

30

According to our estimates, 10% of returning refugees for the average industry can explain larger exports by 1.6%. For the average industry, these numbers are two people and roughly US$200,000 (based on 1990’s exports), respectively. Given that all of our sample corresponds to 17,000 returning refugees, that would represent an increase in exports of nearly US$2 billion. This is about 6% of the difference in total exports between 1990 and 2005, which corresponds to US$34 billion. In our sample, we note that the difference in exports between the years 2000 and 2005 is nearly the same (i.e., exports for the average industry are of similar orders of magnitude both in 1990 and in 2000).

31

Online appendix section C.2.5 exploits the timing of returns of refugees in an event study setting and finds that industries start outperforming earlier when we identify that our treatment kicks in earlier.

32

According to Costinot et al. (2012), Φp,t=e(φp,t/6.53), where figure 6.53 is their estimation of the elasticity of (adjusted) bilateral exports with respect to observed productivity and φp,t is estimated as the country-industry specific productivity parameters for Yugoslavia using the following specification and using the complete matrix of bilateral trade (where Yugoslavia is one of the c countries in the data set): asinh(expc,c',p,t)=φc,p,t+Ωc',p,t+Ψc,c',p+ɛc,c',p,t. In the specification expc,c',p,t is the export value from country c to country c' of industry p in year t, φc,p,t is an exporter-industry-year fixed effect, Ωc',p,t is an importer-industry-year fixed effect, Ψc,c',p is an exporter-importer-industry fixed effect, and ɛc,c',p,t is the error term.

33

As noted above, a large share of people in our data are recorded as Yugoslavian nationals. Bosnia and Herzegovina is the most important successor state of the former Yugoslavia in our setting and also the only one for which we have a sufficient number of cases that we can recalculate the treatment variable specifically for Bosnians (as opposed to other nationalities).

34

Online appendix section B.2 summarizes the values of these characteristics for each one of the occupations in our data set, along with the number of workers in our sample in each occupation.

35

See online appendix section C.5 for tables with all the estimations by group, including both univariate and multivariate regressions. While there is multicollinearity, the relative size of the point estimates remains consistent in univariate and multivariate regressions.

36

In online appendix section C.6, we present results expanding the exercise to all countries as a way to explore external validity, and find consistent results.

Abadie
,
Alberto
,
Alexis
Diamond
, and
Jens
Hainmueller
, “
Synthetic Control Methods for Comparative Case Studies: Estimating the Effect of California’s Tobacco Control Program
,”
Journal of the American Statistical Association
105
:
490
(
2010
),
493
505
.
Abadie
,
Alberto
,
Alexis
Diamond
, and
Jens
Hainmueller
, “
Synth: An R Package for Synthetic Control Methods in Comparative Case Studies
,”
Journal of Statistical Software
42
:
13
(
2011
),
1
17
.
Abadie
,
Alberto
,
Alexis
Diamond
, and
Jens
Hainmueller
, “
Comparative Politics and the Synthetic Control Method
,”
American Journal of Political Science
59
:
2
(
2015
),
495
510
.
Abadie
,
Alberto
, and
Javier
Gardeazabal
, “
The Economic Costs of Conflict: A Case Study of the Basque Country
,”
American Economic Review
93
:
1
(
2003
),
113
132
.
Acemoglu
,
D.
,
T. A.
Hassan
, and
J. A.
Robinson
, “
Social Structure and Development: A Legacy of the Holocaust in Russia
,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics
126
:
2
(
2011
),
895
946
.
Agrawal
,
Ajay
,
Iain
Cockburn
, and
John
McHale
, “
Gone But Not Forgotten: Knowledge Flows, Labor Mobility, and Enduring Social Relationships
,”
Journal of Economic Geography
6
:
5
(
2006
),
571
591
.
Agrawal
,
Ajay
,
Devesh
Kapur
,
John
McHale
, and
Alexander
Oettl
, “
Brain Drain or Brain Bank? The Impact of Skilled Emigration on Poor-Country Innovation
,”
Journal of Urban Economics
69
:
1
(
2011
),
43
55
.
Akbulut-Yuksel
,
Mevlude
, and
Mutlu
Yuksel
, “
The Long-Term Direct and External Effects of Jewish Expulsions in Nazi Germany
,”
American Economic Journal: Economic Policy
7
:
3
(
2015
),
58
85
.
Angrist
,
Joshua D.
, and
Adriana D.
Kugler
, “
Protective or Counter-Productive? Labour Market Institutions and the Effect of Immigration on EU Natives
,”
Economic Journal
113
:
488
(
2003
),
F302–F331
.
Autor
,
David H.
,
Frank
Levy
, and
Richard J.
Murnane
, “
The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration
,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics
1184
(
2003
),
1279
1333
.
Bahar
,
Dany
,
Prithwiraj
Choudhury
, and
Hillel
Rapoport
, “
Migrant Inventors and the Technological Advantage of Nations
,”
Research Policy
49:9 (
2020
), 103947.
Bahar
,
Dany
, and
Hillel
Rapoport
, “
Migration, Knowledge Diffusion and the Comparative Advantage of Nations
,”
Economic Journal
128
:
612
(
2018
),
F273–F375
.
Batista
,
Catia
,
Tara
McIndoe-Calder
, and
Pedro C.
Vicente
, “
Return Migration, Self-Selection and Entrepreneurship
,”
Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics
79
:
5
(
2017
),
797
821
.
Becker
,
Sascha O.
, and
Andreas
Ferrara
, “
Consequences of Forced Migration: A Survey of Recent Findings
,”
Labour Economics
59
:
C
(
2019
),
1
16
.
Bertrand
,
Marianne
,
Esther
Duflo
, and
Sendhil
Mullainathan
, “
How Much Should We Trust Differences-in-Differences Estimates?
Quarterly Journal of Economics
119
:
1
(
2004
),
249
275
.
Besley
,
T.
, and
R.
Burgess
, “
Can Labor Regulation Hinder Economic Performance? Evidence from India
,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics
119
:
1
(
2004
),
91
134
.
Bharadwaj
,
Prashant
,
Asim I.
Khwaja
, and
Atif
Mian
, “
Population Exchange and Its Impact on Literacy, Occupation and Gender: Evidence from the Partition of India
,”
International Migration
53
:
4
(
2015
),
90
106
.
Black
,
Richard
, “
Return and Reconstruction in Bosnia-Herzegovina: Missing Link, or Mistaken Priority?
SAIS Review
21
:
4
(
2001
),
177
199
.
Black
,
Richard
, and
Saskia
Gent
, “
Sustainable Return in Post-Conflict Contexts [Retours durables au lendemain d’un conflit. retorno sostenible en contextos posconflictos]
,”
International Migration
44
:
3
(
2006
),
15
38
.
Bloom
,
Nicholas
,
Benn
Eifert
,
Aprajit
Mahajan
,
David
McKenzie
, and
John
Roberts
, “
Does Management Matter? Evidence from India
,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics
128
:
1
(
2013
),
1
51
.
Bloom
,
Nicholas
,
Kalina
Manova
,
John
Van Reenen
,
Stephen
Teng Sun
, and
Zhihong
Yu
, “
Managing Trade: Evidence from China and the US
,” this review 103:3 (
2021
), 443–460.
Bloom
,
Nicholas
, and
John Van
Reenen
, “
Measuring and Explaining Management Practices across Firms and Countries
,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics
122
(
November
2007
),
1351
1408
.
Blossfeld
,
Hans-Peter
, “
Labor-Market Entry and the Sexual Segregation of Careers in the Federal Republic of Germany
,”
American Journal of Sociology
93
:
1
(
1987
),
89
118
.
Bosswick
,
Wolfgang
, “
Development of Asylum Policy in Germany
,”
Journal of Refugee Studies
13
:
1
(
2000
),
43
60
.
Breschi
,
Stefano
,
Francesco
Lissoni
, and
Ernest
Miguelez
, “
Foreign-Origin Inventors in the USA: Testing for Diaspora and Brain Gain Effects
,”
Journal of Economic Geography
17
:
5
(
2017
),
1009
1038
.
Bryan
,
Gharad
, and
Melanie
Morten
, “
The Aggregate Productivity Effects of Internal Migration: Evidence from Indonesia
,”
Journal of Political Economy
127
:
5
(
2019
),
2229
2268
.
Burchardi
,
Konrad B.
, and
Tarek A.
Hassan
, “
The Economic Impact of Social Ties: Evidence from German Reunification
,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics
128
:
3
(
2013
),
1219
1271
.
Cadot
,
Olivier
,
Celine
Carrere
, and
Vanessa
Strauss-Kahn
, “
Export Diversification: What’s behind the Hump?
” this review
93
:
2
(
2011
),
590
605
.
Card
,
David
,
Jörg
Heining
, and
Patrick
Kline
, “
Workplace Heterogeneity and the Rise of West German Wage Inequality
,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics
128
:
3
(
2013
),
967
1015
.
Choudhury
,
Prithwiraj
, “
Return Migration and Geography of Innovation in MNEs: A Natural Experiment of Knowledge Production by Local Workers Reporting to Return Migrants
,”
Journal of Economic Geography
16
:
3
(
2016
),
585
610
.
Costinot
,
Arnaud
,
Dave
Donaldson
, and
Ivana
Komunjer
, “
What Goods Do Countries Trade? A Quantitative Exploration of Ricardo’s Ideas
,”
Review of Economic Studies
79
(
2012
),
581
608
.
Cuñat
,
Alejandro
, and
Marc J.
Melitz
, “
Volatility, Labor Market Flexibility, and the Pattern of Comparative Advantage
,”
Journal of the European Economic Association
10
:
2
(
2012
),
225
254
.
Dauth
,
Wolfgang
,
Sebastian
Findeisen
, and
Jens
Suedekum
, “
The Rise of the East and the Far East: German Labor Markets and Trade Integration
,”
Journal of the European Economic Association
12
:
6
(
2014
),
1643
1675
.
De Chaisemartin
,
C.
, and
X.
D’Haultfoeuille
, “
Fuzzy Differences-in-Differences
,”
Review of Economic Studies
85
:
2
(
2018
),
999
1028
.
Dengler
,
Katharina
,
Britta
Matthes
, and
Wiebke
Paulus
, “
Occupational Tasks in the German Labour Market: An Alternative Measurement on the Basis of an Expert Database
,”
Institut für Arbeitsmarkt- und Berufsforschung Fdz methodenreport Nürnberg
(
2014
).
Deutscher-Bundestag
, “
Bericht der Beauftragten der Bundesregierung für die Belange der Ausländer über die Lage der Ausländer in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland 1993. BT-Drs. 12/6960
” (
1994
), http://dipbt.bundestag.de/doc/btd/12/069/1206960.pdf
(22.09.2017)
.
Dimova
,
Rozita
, “
Duldung Trauma: Bosnian Refugees in Berlin
” (pp.
47
52
), in
Alice
Szczepaniková
,
Marek
Čaněk
, and
Jan
Grill
(eds.),
Migration Processes in Central and Eastern Europe: Unpacking the Diversity
(
Prague
:
Multicultural Centre Prague
,
2006
).
Dustmann
,
Christian
, and
Albrecht
Glitz
, “
How Do Industries and Firms Respond to Changes in Local Labor Supply?
Journal of Labor Economics
33
:
3
(
2015
),
711
750
.
Dustmann
,
Christian
, and
Oliver
Kirchkamp
, “
The Optimal Migration Duration and Activity Choice after Re-Migration
,”
Journal of Development Economics
67
:
2
(
2002
),
351
372
.
Dustmann
,
Christian
,
Uta
Schönberg
, and
Jan
Stuhler
, “
Labor Supply Shocks, Native Wages, and the Adjustment of Local Employment
,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics
132
:
1
(
2017
),
435
483
.
Easterly
,
William
,
The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists’ Adventures and Misadventures in the Tropics
(
Cambridge, MA
:
MIT Press
,
2001
).
Feenstra
,
Robert C.
,
Robert E.
Lipsey
,
Haiyan
Deng
,
Alyson C.
Ma
, and
Hengyong
Mo
, “
World Trade Flows: 1962–2000
,”
NBER working paper 11040
(
2005
).
Giorcelli
,
Michela
, “
No the Long-Term Effects of Management and Technology Transfers
,”
American Economic Review
109
:
1
(
2019
),
121
152
.
Grosfeld
,
Irena
,
Alexander
Rodnyansky
, and
Ekaterina
Zhuravskaya
, “
Persistent Antimarket Culture: A Legacy of the Pale of Settlement after the Holocaust
,”
American Economic Journal: Economic Policy
5
:
L3
(
2013
),
189
226
.
Hailbronner
,
Kay
, “
National Report Germany
” (pp.
221
244
), in
Kay
Hailbronner
(ed.),
Study on the Single Asylum Procedure One-Stop-Shop against the Background of the Common European Asylum System and the Goal of a Common Asylum Procedure
(
Luxemburg
:
European Commission
,
2003
).
Hausmann
,
Ricardo
,
César A.
Hidalgo
,
Sebastián
Bustos
,
Michele
Coscia
,
Alexander
Simoes
, and
Muhammed A.
Yildirim
,
The Atlas of Economic Complexity: Mapping Paths to Prosperity
(
Cambridge, MA
:
MIT Press
,
2014
).
Hausmann
,
Ricardo
,
Jason
Hwang
, and
Dani
Rodrik
, “
What You Export Matters
,”
Journal of Economic Growth
12
:
1
(
2006
),
1
25
.
Hidalgo
,
César A.
,
Bailey
Klinger
,
A. L.
Barabási
, and
Ricardo
Hausmann
, “
The Product Space Conditions the Development of Nations
,”
Science
317
:
5837
(
2007
),
482
487
.
Hornung
,
Erik
, “
Immigration and the Diffusion of Technology: The Huguenot Diaspora in Prussia
,”
American Economic Review
104
:
1
(
2014
),
84
122
.
Huber
,
Kilian
,
Volker
Lindenthal
, and
Fabian
Waldinger
, “
Discrimination, Managers, and Firm Performance: Evidence from ‘Aryanizations’ in Nazi Germany
,”
Journal of Political Economy
129
:
9
(
2021
),
2455
2503
.
IAB
, “
IAB Employment History (BeH)
,”
IAB Beschäftigtenhistorik (BeH)
,
V10.00.00
,
Nürnberg
(
2015
).
Imbs
,
Jean
, and
Romain
Wacziarg
, “
Stages of Diversification
,”
American Economic Review
93
:
1
(
2003
),
63
86
.
Jaeger
,
David
,
Joakim
Ruist
, and
Jan
Stuhler
, “
Shift-Share Instruments and the Impact of Immigration
,”
NBER working paper
24285
(
2018
).
Kerr
,
William R.
, “
Ethnic Scientific Communities and International Technology Diffusion
,” this review
90
:
3
(
2008
),
518
537
.
Koren
,
Miklos
, and
Silvana
Tenreyro
, “
Volatility and Development
,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics
122
:
1
(
2007
),
243
287
.
Lederer
,
Harald
,
Migration und Integration in Zahlen
(
Bonn
:
europäisches forum für migrationsstudien
,
1997
).
Leromain
,
Elsa
, and
Gianluca
Orefice
, “
New Revealed Comparative Advantage Index: Dataset and Empirical Distribution
,”
International Economics
139
(
2014
),
48
70
.
Liedtke
,
Matthias
, “
National Welfare and Asylum in Germany
,”
Critical Social Policy
22
:
3
(
2002
),
479
497
.
MacKinnon
,
J. G.
, and
Lonnie
Magee
, “
Transforming the Dependent Variable in Regression Models
,”
International Economic Review
31
:
2
(
1990
),
315
339
.
Malchow-Møller
,
Nikolaj
,
Jakob
Roland Munch
, and
Jan
Rose Skaksen
, “
Do Foreign Experts Increase the Productivity of Domestic Firms?
Scandinavian Journal of Economics
12
:
10
(
2017
),
3218
3221
.
Markusen
,
James R.
, and
Natalia
Trofimenko
, “
Teaching Locals New Tricks: Foreign Experts as a Channel of Knowledge Transfers
,”
Journal of Development Economics
88
:
1
(
2009
),
120
131
.
Mayda
,
Anna Maria
,
Christopher
Parsons
,
Han
Pham
, and
Pierre-Louis
Vézina
, “
Refugees and Foreign Direct Investment: Quasi-Experimental Evidence from U.S. Resettlements
,”
Journal of Development Economics
156 (
2022
), 102818.
McCormick
,
Barry
, and
Jackline
Wahba
, “
Overseas Work Experience, Savings and Enterpreneurship amongst Return Migrants to LDCs
,”
Scottish Journal of Political Economy
48
:
2
(
2001
),
164
178
.
Mesnard
,
Alice
, “
Temporary Migration and Capital Market Imperfections
,”
Oxford Economic Papers
56
:
2
(
2004
),
242
262
.
Miguélez
,
Ernest
, “
Inventor Diasporas and the Internationalization of Technology
,”
World Bank Economic Review
32
:
1
(
2018
),
41
63
.
Miguelez
,
Ernest
, and
Claudia Noumedem
Temgoua
, “
Inventor Migration and Knowledge Flows: A Two-Way Communication Channel?
Research Policy
49
:
9
(
2020
).
Nenadic
,
Mario
,
Nermina
Dzepar-Ganibegovic
,
Medzid
Lipjankic
,
Drago
Borovcanin
,
Nada
Spasojevic
,
Dragana
Kovac
, and
Abela
Pobrić
,
Comparative Analysis on Access to Rights of Refugees and Displaced Persons
(
Skopje
:
Ministry for Human Rights and Refugees
,
2005
).
Parsons
,
Christopher
, and
Pierre-Louis
Vézina
, “
Migrant Networks and Trade: The Vietnamese Boat People as a Natural Experiment
,”
Economic Journal
128
:
612
(
2018
),
F210–F234
.
Pascali
,
Luigi
, “
Banks and Development: Jewish Communities in the Italian Renaissance and Current Economic Performance
,” this review
98
:
1
(
2016
),
140
158
.
Poole
,
Jennifer
, “
Knowledge Transfers from Multinational to Domestic Firms: Evidence from Worker Mobility
,” this review
95
:
2
(
2013
),
393
406
.
Radovic
,
B.
, “
A Brief Retrospective on the Problem of Refugees in the Yugoslav Wars 1991–99
” (pp.
11
26
), in
G.
Opacic
,
I.
Vidakovic
, and
B.
Vujadinovic
(eds.),
Living in Post-War Communities
(
Belgrade
:
International Aid Network
,
2005
).
Rapoport
,
Hillel
, and
Frédéric
Docquier
, “
The Economics of Migrants’ Remittances
” (pp.
1135
1198
), in
Serge-Christophe
Kolm
and
Jean Mercier
Ythier
(eds.),
Applications
(
Amsterdam
:
Elsevier
,
2006
).
Rauch
,
James E.
, and
Vitor
Trindade
, “
Ethnic Chinese Networks in International Trade
,” this review
84
:
1
(
2002
),
116
130
.
Rhee
,
Yung
, and
Therese
Belot
, “
Export Catalysts in Low-Income Countries
,”
World Bank discussion paper, technical report 72
(
1990
).
Ruben
,
Ruerd
,
Marieke
Van Houte
, and
Tine
Davids
, “
What Determines the Embeddedness of Forced-Return Migrants? Rethinking the Role of Pre- and Post-Return Assistance
,”
International Migration Review
43
:
4
(
2009
),
908
937
.
Ruhl
,
Stefan
, and
Harald W.
Lederer
,
Migrationsbericht 2001 der Ausländerbeauftragten im Auftrag der Bundesregierung
(
Beauftragte der Bundesregierung für Ausländerfragen
,
2001
).
Scoville
,
Warren C.
, “
The Huguenots and the Diffusion of Technology, I
,”
Journal of Political Economy
60
:
4
(
1952a
),
294
311
.
Scoville
,
Warren C.
, “
The Huguenots and the Diffusion of Technology, II
,”
Journal of Political Economy
60
:
5
(
1952b
),
392
411
.
Testa
,
Patrick A.
, “
The Economic Legacy of Expulsion: Lessons from Post-War Czechoslovakia
,”
Economic Journal
131
:
637
(
2020
),
2233
2271
.
UNHCR, “
After the War Was Over
,”
Refugee Magazine
3
:
140
(
2005
),
1
32
.
Wahba
,
Jackline
, and
Yves
Zenou
, “
Out of Sight, Out of Mind: Migration, Entrepreneurship and Social Capital
,”
Regional Science and Urban Economics
42
:
5
(
2012
),
890
903
.
Waldinger
,
Fabian
, “
Quality Matters: The Expulsion of Professors and the Consequences for PhD Student Outcomes in Nazi Germany
,”
Journal of Political Economy
118
:
4
(
2010
),
787
831
.
Waldinger
,
F.
, “
Peer Effects in Science: Evidence from the Dismissal of Scientists in Nazi Germany
,”
Review of Economic Studies
79
:
2
(
2012
),
838
861
.
Walker
,
William S.
,
German and Bosnian Voices in a Time of Crisis: Bosnian Refugees in Germany, 1992–2002
(
Indianapolis
:
Dog Ear Publishing
,
2010
).

Author notes

This paper benefited from helpful comments at various stages by Ran Abramitzky, Simone Bertoli, Clément De Chaisemartin, Michael Clemens, Wolfgang Dauth, David Yanagizawa-Drott, Esther Duflo, Peter Egger, Albrecht Glitz, Simon Goerlach, Bill Kerr, Florian Lehmer, Britta Matthes, Anna Maria Mayda, Thierry Mayer, Nathan Nunn, Ariell Reshef, and participants in many different seminars and conferences who provided valuable comments. We are grateful to Valentin Todorov from UNIDO for data guidance. Rotem Weinberg provided excellent research assistance. H.R, and C.Ö. acknowledge the support of EUR grant ANR-17-EURE-0001. All errors are our own.

A supplemental appendix is available online at https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_01165.

Supplementary data